Cash transfers in the developing world – 2013 version

We have published a more recent review of this intervention. See our most recent report on cash transfers.


In a nutshell

  • The Program: Giving unconditional cash grants to poor people in low-income countries.
  • Track record: Cash transfers are one of the most-studied development interventions, though evidence drawing a direct connection to particular humanitarian outcomes is sparse. We put the most weight on a randomized controlled trial of the short-term effects of a variant of GiveDirectly's program. This trial indicated that unconditional cash grants lead to large increases in recipients' consumption, assets, business investment, and revenue, but did not observe a short-term increase in profits. Studies of cash transfer programs that differ in meaningful ways from GiveDirectly's have suggested that transfers may be invested at high rates of return over the long term.
  • Cost-effectiveness: Cost-effectiveness calculations are extremely sensitive to many assumptions, and cash transfers are in the same range of cost-effectiveness of other priority programs we have considered.
  • Bottom line: Cash transfers have the strongest track record we've seen for a non-health intervention, and are a priority program of ours.


Published: December 2012; Updated: November 2013 (2012 version)

Table of Contents

Program description

There are three types of cash transfer programs that have been studied:

  • Conditional cash transfers (CCTs), in which recipients receive cash only if they fulfill various requirements such as rates of school attendance or visits to health centers. There is a subset of CCTs in which the conditions are announced but are not formally monitored, so all participants receive a transfer regardless of compliance with the announced conditions.1
  • Unconditional cash transfers (UCTs), in which selected participants receive funds without a requirement to meet additional conditions.
  • Business grant programs, in which unconditional in-kind or cash grants are given to micro-enterprises that have no paid employees other than the owners.

The program conducted by GiveDirectly, is different from most of the cash transfer programs that have previously been studied because it aims to transfer wealth rather than income, and not exclusively to business-owners. In practice, this means that participants receive large sums of money (~100% of per-capita annual consumption) over a relatively short period of time (~8 months), with no formal or informal restrictions on how the funds are used.

We review the results of all three different types of cash transfer programs that have been studied, including a randomized controlled trial of a variant of GiveDirectly's program, in order to address the likely effects of GiveDirectly's cash transfers. In the case of conditional cash transfers, we focus on impacts that do not seem relevant to the conditionality itself, e.g., impacts on consumption rather than on school attendance or other behaviors that are conditions of receiving the transfers.

The appeal of cash transfers

Cash transfers are potentially attractive for individual donors because they allow the recipients of charity to choose how to spend funds allocated for them. Provided that local markets can supply it, if the recipients feel that they need food, they can use their cash to purchase it; if they need medical care, they can buy it; if they have a business, they can invest in it. As we wrote in 2009:

Which would you bet on to get water to people in Kenya: an organization funded by wealthy Americans (motivated by guilt and the wish to display generosity, among other things), or an organization funded by Kenyan customers (motivated by a need for water)?

Why do cash handouts seem to be so rare in the charity world? Perhaps it’s because extensive experience and study have shown this approach to be inferior to others. Or perhaps it has more to do with the fact that giving out cash fundamentally puts the people, rather than the charity, in control.

Program Track Record

Below is a list of the cash transfer programs evaluated by randomized controlled trials (RCTs) that we reviewed for our initial report in 2012.2 This list includes basic information about the program and key findings from the RCT that studied the program. We discuss many of the studies in more detail on our old cash transfer review page. For a list of the studies we identified in our 2013 update of this report, see this footnote.3

Program CCT, UCT, Business grant? Conditions Size and frequency Key Findings
Oportunidades (formerly PROGRESA) (1997-), Mexico4 CCT Health: checkups for all in household, lectures for 15+; Education: 80% attendance, complete middle school, complete grade 12 before 22.5 20% of PCE;6 bimonthly7 10-20% increase in food consumption (more); 6% increase in long-term consumption (more)
Programa de Asignacion Familiar (PRAF)(1998- ), Honduras8 CCT Health visits and 85% school enrollment9 9% of PCE;10 every 6 months11 N/A (all outcomes measured were conditioned outcomes)
Red De Proteccion Social (RPS) (2000-), Nicaragua12 CCT Health: workshops, regular health care visits, up-to-date vaccinations, adequate weight gain; Education: enrollment, 85% attendance, grade promotion.13 27% of PCE;14 bimonthly15 ~15% increase in household expenditures; ~25% increase in food expenditures; no increase in investment (more)
Atencion a Crisis (2005), Nicaragua16 CCT Education: enrollment, 85% attendance; occupational training course; business grant plan.17 18% of PCE;18 bimonthly19 ~30% higher food consumption; more use of health services; improved self-reported health but unimproved on anthropometric measures (more)
Bono de Desarrollo Humano (2003-), Ecuador20 CCT but not monitored No monitoring. Without being monitored: Health check-ups (0-5), Education: enrollment, 90% attendance.21 10% of PCE;22 monthly23 Mixed impact on school enrollment, child labor and cognitive development (more)
Programa Apoyo Alimentario, Mexico24 CCT but not monitored No monitored conditions25 11.5% of pre-transfer consumption;26 bimonthly27 Slight improvements in weight for in-kind transfers (not for cash); slight decrease in self-reported sickness for both (more)
Zomba Cash Transfer Program, Malawi (2008-)28 CCT & UCT Unconditional group and conditional group (80% or better school attendance)29 15% of household consumption;30 monthly31 Improved school attendance & performance (more for conditional transfers); reduced psychological distress during but not after transfer period
Cash Transfer for Orphans and Vulnerable Children (CT-OVC), Kenya (2007-)32 UCT Unconditional 21% of household spending;33 monthly34 Increase food consumption by 17% (more); may increase school enrollment amongst older students
Micro-enterprise RCT, Sri Lanka (2005)35 Grant Unconditional36 32.5% of annual profits;37 once38 >60% annual return on investment via increased business profits for two years, continuing for at least five years for men but not women, with no clear differences between cash and in-kind grants (more)
Micro-enterprise RCT, Ghana (2009)39 Grant Unconditional 12% of annual profits;40 once41 No statistically significant impact on business profits for cash grants; ~20% monthly returns for in-kind grants (more)
Micro-enterprise RCT, Mexico (2005-2006)42 Grant Unconditional43 4% of annual profits;44 once45 Returns of 28 to 46% per month based on impact on business profits, with indistinguishable differences between cash and in-kind grants (more)

A more detailed version of this table is available here (XLS).

How do people spend the money they receive via cash transfers?

GiveDirectly's program is substantially different from nearly all cash transfer programs that have previously been studied. Accordingly, it is not clear that evidence from most academic studies (of very differently-structured cash transfer programs) will provide accurate estimates of the effect of GiveDirectly's cash transfers on their recipients; GiveDirectly's transfers might be either far more or far less effective than more conventionally-structured cash transfers:

  • receiving large lump sums might lead people to spend more frivolously; or
  • lump sums might be invested at higher rates than ongoing transfers would be, leading to higher long-term consumption.

For this reason, in assessing GiveDirectly's impact, we put the most weight on the results of an RCT of a variant of GiveDirectly's program, discussed below. Despite the questions about the applicability of the evidence from other cash transfer programs to GiveDirectly's programs, we review this evidence below.

Food

Note: the section below was published in December 2012. In September-October 2013, we searched for additional literature on cash transfers and did not find any studies that substantively changed our views (more on our research process here). Of all the recent literature, we put the most significant weight on an RCT of a variant of GiveDirectly's program. For more on how recipients spent funds in this study, see below.

As discussed at our old in-depth review of cash transfer impacts, most of the studies we have reviewed on cash transfers show meaningful impacts on food consumption (~20% increase over baseline/control group spending on food). In addition, the World Bank's review states, "There is a good deal of evidence that households that receive CCTs spend more on food and, within the food basket, on higher-quality sources of nutrients than do households that do not receive the transfer but have comparable overall income or consumption levels"46 - such as milk, meat, fruits, vegetables, and eggs.47

Across the four randomized control trials where it is measured in comparable terms, increases in spending on food makes up more than half of the transfer amount:

  • In a randomized study of the Mexican Oportunidades conditional cash transfer program, approximately three quarters of transfers are estimated to be spent on food.48
  • A second study from Mexico, of the Programa Apoyo Alimentario, an unmonitored conditional cash transfer, found that nearly all (94%) of cash transfers were spent on food.49
  • A randomized study of the RPS conditional cash transfer program in Nicaragua estimated that roughly three quarters of the transfer was spent on food.
    50
  • In a randomized control trial of the CT-OVC unconditional cash transfer program in Kenya, roughly half of transfers are spent on food.51

Alcohol and tobacco

Note: the section below was published in December 2012. In September-October 2013, we searched for additional literature on this topic and did not find any studies that substantively changed our views (more on our research process here). Of all the recent literature, we put the most significant weight on an RCT of a variant of GiveDirectly's program, which did not find an increase in spending on alcohol or tobacco. For more on recipients' spending on alcohol and tobacco in this study, see below.

Cash transfers could be used for alcohol or tobacco, which may have adverse effects.

Three randomized controlled trials of cash transfers that report spending on alcohol or tobacco do not find large increases due to cash transfers:

  • A randomized study of the Programa de Apoyo Alimentario food security program in Mexico, which had formal conditions that were not enforced, found that cash transfers caused an increase in alcohol consumption equivalent to 1.5% of the value of the transfer, and no increase in tobacco consumption.52 The authors add, "Only 5% of households report consuming alcohol in any amount. This is most likely an underestimate as the survey was usually answered by the female head of the households who might not be aware of all alcohol purchases by other family members. Importantly, given the large increase in consumption of non-alcohol goods under both transfer types, there is little leeway for household members to purchase non-recorded alcohol."53
  • In a randomized study of the Nicaraguan conditional cash transfer program Red de Protección Social, alcohol and tobacco made up 0.5% of food expenditures, and the effect of cash transfers was small (0.1% of food expenditures) and statistically insignificant.54 However, this study also states, "Information about alcohol and tobacco expenditures in these types of surveys is often unreliable; it is presented separately and we draw no conclusions from the reported information."55
  • A randomized evaluation of Kenya's CT-OVC unconditional cash transfer program found a small and statistically insignificant decrease in alcohol consumption.56

In all three studies, these results come from surveys of how people spend money in general, rather than specifically asking about the spending of cash transfer funds, and then comparing reported spending on alcohol and tobacco across the treatment and control groups. Different forms of misreporting of spending would have different effects on the validity of the estimates, but we would guess that the misreporting would lead the estimated effects to be biased downward (i.e. to underestimate the effect of transfers on alcohol consumption).57

Taking into account the three studies and the potential for bias, we would guess that any increases in consumption of alcohol or tobacco due to cash transfers would be small.

Investment

Note: the section below was published in December 2012. In September-October 2013, we searched for additional literature on this topic and did not find any studies that substantively changed our views (more on our research process here). Of all the recent literature, we put the most significant weight on an RCT of a variant of GiveDirectly's program. For more on how recipients spent funds in this study, see below.

We have seen five studies examining the extent to which people invest their cash transfers, leading to longer-term gains:

  • Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012 is a followup of a randomized rollout of the Oportunidades program in Mexico, in which the treatment group was randomly selected to receive conditional cash transfers a year and a half earlier than the control group. It finds that people in the treatment group saw faster increases in their ownership of farm assets like land, started more microenterprises--“mainly production of handcrafts for sale”--and ultimately saw ~5% higher consumption levels than those in the control group, even four years after the latter had been enrolled in the program.58 The authors estimate that 74% of transfers are consumed and 26% are invested, an estimate that we discuss in more depth below.59 They go on to say:60
    Note that our estimate of the [marginal propensity to consume] MPC is consistent with other estimates in developing countries. For example, Musgrove (1979) estimates MPCs of 0.881 for urban Colombia, 0.896 for urban Ecuador, and, 0.776 for urban Peru; and Bhalla (1979) reports an MPC of 0.61 for rural India. Moreover, its value is relatively high, which is suggestive that beneficiaries are perceiving the program as a permanent—as opposed to transitory—source of income: Paxson (1992) reports MPCs out of permanent income from 0.56 to 0.84, and MPCs out of transitory income ranging from 0.17 to 0.27 for a sample of rice farmers in Thailand.
  • A randomized evaluation of the Nicaraguan Red de Protección Social, a conditional cash transfer program, did not find any change in investment (except in human capital) due to the cash transfers.61 However, the authors note that, “households are indeed following the recommendations of the program; that is, they are spending most of their income from the program on current (food and education) expenditures.”62
  • A randomized evaluation of the Kenya Cash Transfer for Orphans and Vulnerable Children (CT-OVC), an ongoing unconditional cash transfer program, found that 87% of the transfer was consumed.63 The remaining 13% is not accounted for by the study, but the authors speculate that it may be invested.64 It could also have been saved (without investment), transferred to other individuals, or simply mis-measured.65
  • In a randomized study of unconditional grants to micro-enterprises without any paid employees in Sri Lanka, recipients reported that 58% of their unconditional grants were immediately invested in the business, another 12% was saved, and the remaining 30% was spent on household consumption, investment, or other uses.66 Measures of the impact of the grants on capital stock show more dramatic effects, suggesting that cash grants increase capital stock for the recipient's micro-enterprise by as much as 100% of the grant amount.67
  • A similar randomized study of unconditional grants to micro-enterprises without any paid employees in Ghana estimated that cash grants to women increased household spending by 50-80% of their value during the quarter following grant receipt and cash grants to men increased household spending by 33-50% of their value, though the estimate for men was not statistically significant. The variation in estimated spending, especially amongst women, arises from very high levels of household spending amongst relatively few individuals, though the results for women remain significant after truncating at various levels.68

    The estimated effects of the cash grants on business capital stock were not statistically significant, but varied between roughly one third and one half of the transfer value for women and between roughly zero and 20% of the transfer value for men, depending on whether full or truncated values were used.69

Note, though, that the cash transfers by GiveDirectly are both larger and made to poorer individuals than any of the transfers discussed above:

  • Economic theory and the citations quoted above from Gertler, Martinez, and Rubio-Codina (2012) suggest that larger, shorter term transfers are more likely to be invested than smaller, ongoing transfers, and comparing the results from the ongoing cash transfers and the business grants appears to bear this conclusion out, though the estimates overlap significantly.
  • However, there is also a potential tradeoff with beneficiary wealth: poorer recipients are typically expected to consume more of a cash transfer, relative to wealthier individuals. This coincides with our worry that GiveDirectly's focus on targeting the poorest may be systematically targeting individuals who are less likely to invest or, if they do invest, to reap large returns.

What return on investment do cash-transfer recipients earn?

Note: the section below was originally published in December 2012. In September-October 2013, we searched for additional literature on this topic (more on our research process here). Of all the recent literature, we put the most significant weight on an RCT of a variant of GiveDirectly's program in which recipients earned substantially smaller returns. Two other new studies found high returns from unconditional cash grants with features encouraging investment.70 In November 2013, we updated this section to include results from these three studies.

A variant of GiveDirectly

Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, an RCT of a variant of GiveDirectly's program found that 23% of recipients invested large portions of their transfers in iron roofs, which have investment returns of between 7% and 14%.71 Participants also increased their spending on various enterprises, which lead to increased revenues but no measurable increase in profit and therefore no additional returns.72

This suggests that GiveDirectly recipients may earn substantially lower returns than participants in cash transfer programs with features encouraging investment. However, because of the study’s short-term nature, we cannot confidently determine whether GiveDirectly recipients' investments may need more time to mature and may have larger returns in the long-run. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 is discussed in much more detail below.

Unconditional wealth transfers with features encouraging investment

Two studies of unconditional wealth transfers in Uganda both found high annual returns of 30%-39% on the original grant.73 Both of these programs included many features designed to encourage investment and improve returns, which distinguish them from GiveDirectly's intervention. The studies are discussed in more detail below.

Conditional cash transfers

The only randomized controlled trial of ongoing cash transfers that discusses the returns that recipients earn on their investments is based on the Oportunidades conditional cash transfer program in Mexico, described above. Gertler, Martinez, and Rubio-Codina (2012) estimates that, four years after the control group began to receive treatment and five and a half years after the treatment group began to receive transfers, the treatment group continued to have consumption 5.6% higher than the control group.74 This implies, by our calculation, a 1.7% monthly return, and a 21% annual return, on the transfers,75 which further implies a 3.6% monthly, and 42.6% annual, rate of return on investment.76

Using a different method, Gertler, Martinez, and Rubio-Codina (2012) estimates that for every hundred dollars transferred more than two years ago, recipients continue to earn $1.60 per month in additional income, for an annual return of 19.2%, even though they estimate that only 26% of transfers are invested.77 Since only 26% of transfers are invested, this implies an even higher rate of return on investments, of roughly 75% per year, or 6% per month.78

In these calculations, the authors do not rely purely on the randomized comparison between the treatment and control group. Instead, they estimate current consumption as a result of current and past cumulative transfers, which depend both on the randomized roll-out of the program, and on the number, age, gender, and school attendance of the children in a family. While the number, age, and gender of children are plausibly exogenous (i.e. they are not influenced by current consumption), and thus can just be included in the regressions as controls, the school attendance of children in the family is endogenous: worse school attendance is likely to lead to both decreased transfers (since the conditions punish families for not sending children to school) and increased consumption, since children not in school may be more likely to work.

For exogenous variation in the transfers, the authors use instruments consisting of the maximum amount of transfers that the family could have received had their children had perfect attendance.79 This explains a large portion of the variation in actual transfers received, and is likely exogenous (i.e. maximum potential transfers are likely “as good as random” once family demographics are controlled for, and family demographics are likely not influenced by consumption).

Regressing current consumption on the current transfers and cumulative transfers from previous years, the authors estimate that every $100 in current transfers translates into an additional $48.70 of reported spending during the past month, and every $100 in transfers from more than 2 years ago translates into an additional $1.50 of reported spending during the past month.80 However, this is likely to be an underestimate of the total effect because many students worked, causing both a reduction in transfers for them relative to the maximum possible and an increase in consumption for their families (through their wages).81 By assuming that maximum potential transfers influence current consumption only through actually received transfers, which seems plausible, (i.e. by using maximum potential transfers as an instrument for actual transfers) the authors estimate that $100 of actually received transfers this month increases consumption by $74, and $100 of actually received transfers from more than two years ago increases consumption this month by $1.60.82

The authors pursue this instrumental variables strategy, rather than just regressing current consumption on total realized transfers, because the realized transfers are negatively correlated with consumption because of the child labor effects of conditionality, which would lead to an underestimate of the effects of transfers.

The three different estimates discussed for long-term annual returns on cash transfers are quite similar (20.4%, 18%, 19.2%), though the estimated returns on investment differ significantly (42.6%, 35%, 73.8%), because of different estimates of how much of the transfers are consumed.

Business grants

These estimated returns seem quite high, but there is a separate literature on the returns to capital in micro-enterprises that is relevant to this issue. In a series of experiments in Sri Lanka, Mexico, and Ghana, researchers giving grants on the order of $100 to micro-enterprises without any paid employees have found high returns on investment, in the range of 6%-46% per month:

  • A series of papers by de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff based on a randomized controlled trial of one-time grants to micro-enterprises in Sri Lanka have found large positive effects on profits for male owners.83 Approximately five years after initially making grants of $100-$200, divided between cash and in-kind gifts, to microenterprises that did not have any non-owner employees, the authors found $8-$12 higher monthly profits in male-owned businesses that received grants.84 This translates to a 6-12% monthly real return amongst male-owned businesses (with no measured benefits amongst businesses owned by women).85 In earlier work covering the first two years after the grants were made, the authors found similar monthly rates of return, and could not reject the hypothesis that cash and in-kind grants had similar effects on profits.86 During the first two years after the grants were made, the combined effect of the cash on men and women was large and statistically significant, though the returns for men were substantially larger than for women,87 but after five years, the combined effect for men and women appears to no longer be statistically significant (this is our conjecture; we cannot confirm it without examining the raw data and calculations for the study, which we have not done).88
  • In a similar randomized experiment conducted in Ghana, with a larger sample size and shorter follow-up period, Fafchamps et al. (2011) found comparable large effects on microenterprise profits for in-kind transfers (~20% return per month), but effects on business profits for cash were statistically indistinguishable from zero.89 As discussed above, this may be a result of recipients spending transfers in the household rather than investing in their businesses.
  • A similar randomized controlled trial in Mexico, which gave cash or in-kind grants of about $140 to retail micro-enterprises (all owned by men and without paid employees), found returns to capital of 28 to 46% per month over a 3-12 month follow-up period, with indistinguishable differences between cash and in-kind grants.90 The biggest effects (~100% return per month) were concentrated within the 38% of micro-enterprises that were very credit-constrained.91 Although the effects in the credit-constrained subgroup were large and precisely-estimated, the study suffered from substantial attrition (>50% in both treatment and control groups, with similar rates for the two), harming its power and calling the accuracy of the estimates into question.92

RCT of GiveDirectly’s program

We place very high weight on the results of Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, a publicly pre-registered, randomized controlled trial of a variant of GiveDirectly’s program in Rarieda, Western Kenya, because the intervention it evaluated was the most similar to GiveDirectly’s standard program out of all of the RCTs we have seen and because it explicitly addressed issues related to selective reporting bias and multiple comparison problems.93 The trial differed from GiveDirectly’s standard program in one key way: while GiveDirectly currently transfers $1,000 to program recipients, 73% of treatment group members in the evaluation received just $287, less than 30% of the standard amount (one smaller treatment arm did receive $1,085 transfers).94 When interpreting the results, we keep this difference in mind because we believe that the size of a transfer probably has substantial effects on the magnitude of its impact and its effect on recipients’ behavior.

How the program worked

GiveDirectly is an organization that delivers unconditional cash transfers to poor households in Kenya through a mobile money system called M-Pesa.95 While it has altered its model for various experiments, GiveDirectly’s standard model involves transferring $1,000 to poor households, which are identified by their use of thatch roofs.96 Please see our review of GiveDirectly for much more detail on GiveDirectly’s program.

Haushofer and Shapiro 2013’s evaluation of GiveDirectly was randomized on two levels: eligible villages were randomly sorted into treatment and control groups and eligible households within treatment villages were randomized again into treatment households and controls.97 Researchers were therefore able to calculate treatment effects by comparing treatment households to control households within treatment villages.98 They could also calculate the spillover effects the transfers had on non-recipients by comparing control households in treatment villages to otherwise similar households in control villages.99

Different variations of the program were evaluated. Treatment households were cross-randomized into three arms, which varied the gender of the recipient (when households had both male and female household heads), the frequency of the transfer (lump-sum v. monthly installment), and the size of the transfer ($287 v. $1,085).100 The study measured short-term effects of the transfer.101 The time between end-line survey and receipt of final transfer ranged from zero months (for households still receiving transfers when they were surveyed) to fifteen months.102

Effects on GiveDirectly recipients

It is difficult to interpret the size of the main treatment effects reported in Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 because embedded within the “main treatment” were two different transfer sizes ($287 and $1,085), which we would expect to have very different impacts and to be spent in very different ways. The mean transfer size was about $513, which is about half of the size of GiveDirectly’s standard transfer. 103 We also note that we have reported transfer sizes in exchange-rate adjusted terms, but outcomes are reported in purchasing power parity (PPP) adjusted U.S. dollars.104

Except for where we explicitly state otherwise, all results mentioned in this intervention report are statistically significant at the 95% level.

How GiveDirectly transfers were spent

Researchers collected data by surveying members of the treatment and control groups about their recent spending. All data that follows comes from participant self-reports. GiveDirectly recipients increased the value of their non-land assets and their monthly consumption.105 Their spending is broken down in more detail below.

  • Total non-land assets.106 Receipt of transfers increased households’ non-land assets by an average of $279.107 Households that received large transfers increased their total non-land assets by about $253 more than households that received small transfers.108 The largest categories of asset increases were livestock ($85), durable goods ($53; primarily furniture), and savings ($10).109 Transfers also increased the likelihood that a household had an iron roof by 23 percentage points.110 Recipients of large transfers were 23 percentage points more likely to have iron roofs at end-line than recipients of small transfers.111 Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 estimated that iron roofs cost about $564 USD PPP and had a return on investment of between 7 and 14%, but the source of this data was unexplained.112
  • Business expenses. Treatment households spent about $13 per month more than control households on business expenses, which were primarily made up of non-durable expenses on non-agricultural businesses.113 There was no evidence that recipients of large transfers invested more in business expenses than recipients of small transfers.114
  • Health expenditures Treatment households spent about $3 per month more than control households on health expenditures.115 There was no evidence that recipients of large transfers spent more on healthcare than recipients of small transfers.116 This spending was also included within the estimate of spending on consumption, below.
  • Education expenditures. The average treatment household with children spent about $19 more per month on education than the average control household with children although this estimate was imprecisely measured and not statistically different from zero.117 There was no evidence that households receiving large transfers spent more on education than households receiving small transfers.118 This spending was also included within the estimate of spending on consumption, below.
  • Consumption. Treatment households consumed about $36 more per month than control households.119 According to point estimates, recipients of large transfers spent about $20 per month more on consumption than recipients of small transfers but this difference was not statistically different from zero.120 Slightly more than half of this additional consumption was on food.121 This additional consumption also included increased spending on social expenditures and various other expenditures.122
  • Alcohol and tobacco. Treatment households did not increase their spending on alcohol or on tobacco.123

Impacts of GiveDirectly transfers on recipients

  • Food security. At baseline, food security was low among participants.124 Program participants reported a 0.25 standard deviation increase in a food security index over controls.125 Some food security related variables improved more for recipients of large transfers, but the study did not have high enough power to determine whether there was an effect on the overall index.126
  • Health and education. The study did not detect an effect on indices of health and educational outcomes.127
  • Revenue and profits. Receipt of transfers lead to a $17 per month increase in total revenues but no detectable increase in profits.128 We emphasize that these are very short-run effects and we do not know whether participants’ business investments might lead to profits in the longer run. There is no evidence that large transfers had greater effects on revenue or profits.129

Researchers also considered more subjective measures of impact on recipients' quality of life:

  • Psychological well-being. Treatment improved an index of psychological wellbeing by 0.20 standard deviations.130 There was no observable effect on cortisol for the treatment group as a whole although cortisol, an indicator of stress, was slightly lower in the large transfer group than the small transfer group, a difference that was statistically significant at the 10% level when controls were included in the model .131 Recipients of large transfers measure 0.35 standard deviations higher on the well-being index than recipients of small transfers.132
  • Female empowerment. Control households in treatment villages measure 0.23 standard deviations higher on an index of female empowerment than control households in control villages.133 This suggests that cash transfers to a village unexpectedly empowered females in both recipient and non-recipient households. The researchers propose potential mechanisms for this effect, but are explicit that these measured results are surprising and warrant further investigation.134 Note that we report this result for the sake of comprehensiveness but would guess that it is more likely to be random than real.

Spillover effects and village-level effects

Other than the potential positive effects on female empowerment, Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 found no statistically significant spillover effects (i.e., effects on non-recipient households in recipient villages).135 However, imprecise and statistically insignificant point estimates suggest the possibility of moderate negative effects on non-recipient households.136

The study found no evidence of village-wide impacts on prices, wages, or crime but estimates are imprecise.137

Program variations

The study did not find statistically discernible differences when it varied the gender of the recipient.138 There was some evidence suggesting that recipients of lump-sum transfers were more likely to purchase assets and recipients of monthly installments were more likely to spend their transfers on food.139

Limitations

  • Size of transfers. The main treatment effect in the study represented a pooled effect for 128 households that received $1,085 and 343 households that received $287.140 Results were not disaggregated by transfer size and it is difficult to interpret the meaning of the pooled effects of two transfers of such disparate sizes. Estimates of the relative effects of large and small transfers are helpful but cannot be used to back out disaggregated effects and are also somewhat imprecise because only 128 households received large transfers. For nearly all outcomes other than spillovers, the RCT supports the intuitive conclusion that large transfers have more positive effects than small ones, so the main treatment effect can be treated as an extreme lower bound for the effect of the standard program.141
  • Spillover and village-level effects: differences from GiveDirectly’s standard model. Large transfers might have very different spillover effects and village-level effects from small transfers. Spillover effects and village-level effects also might be larger in GiveDirectly’s standard model, where all eligible households in treatment villages receive transfers, than in the RCT, where a control group within the village does not receive transfers.
  • Medium and long-term results. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 is a short-term evaluation of GiveDirectly. We do not know whether the additional consumption enabled by the transfers will persist over the long-term and whether households’ investment in business expenditures might lead to long-term profits.142 The long-term effects of cash transfers are a key question that affects our estimate of the intervention’s cost effectiveness.
  • Dynamics of transfers. The dynamics of the program’s effects are particularly difficult to interpret because some households were still receiving payments at the time of the survey while others received their final transfers more than a year prior to the endline survey.143 Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 may have underestimated effects on investment spending and farm revenue by asking backwards looking questions about treatment households’ spending in time periods before some households received their transfers.144
  • Data on roofs. The study reported that participants’ spending on iron roofs had a simple return of 7% to 14%.145 However, the methodology used to identify the costs of purchasing an iron roof or the costs of repairing the thatch roofs that they replaced was not described. We do not know how much certainty to place in this figure, which also substantially affects the study’s calculation of transfers’ effects on total assets.146 Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 is a “policy brief” and more detailed methodology may become available when the full publication is released.
  • Lack of statistical power The study included 471 households cross-randomized among three treatment arms, which led to eight possible treatment groups.147 Some treatment arms therefore have fairly small sample sizes (for example, only 128 households received large transfers) and estimates of relative effects of treatment arms are imprecise.
  • Self-reporting bias. Outcome data in this study are self-reported, which could lead to positive bias if treatment households sought to please researchers with their use of the transfers. We are especially concerned that treatment households might under-report their use of alcohol and tobacco.
  • Positive bias due to negative spillovers. The study estimates treatment effects by comparing treatment households in treatment villages to control households in treatment villages.148 If transfers had negative spillover effects on control households in treatment villages, estimates of their effects on recipients would be overestimated. The researchers address this issue explicitly in their paper.149

Our interpretation of the results

We place high weight on Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 because we believe it is a well-executed, pre-registered RCT and because it directly measures variations on GiveDirectly’s program. We believe that the RCT supports the notion that, in the short-run, participating in GiveDirectly is likely to increase recipients’ assets and consumption.150

The study is a significant data point for our estimate of the likely return on investment achieved by GiveDirectly recipients. The evidence found of a positive return on investment was the approximately 7%-14% return on purchases of iron roofs, a lower reported return on investment than other studies of cash transfers that are explicitly targeted to business investment (as discussed above).151 On average, treatment increased possession of iron roofs by 23%, with a substantially higher effect for recipients of large transfers.152 Because of the study’s short-term nature, we cannot confidently determine whether recipients’ increased spending on livestock, agriculture, non-agricultural businesses, and (possibly) education have positive returns but, as of the time of the end-line survey, recipients’ additional business spending had not yielded additional profits.153

Conclusion

Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 supports the notion that GiveDirectly has meaningful impacts on asset holdings and consumption for recipients. However, it also provides initial evidence that GiveDirectly recipients are unlikely to invest their transfers at high returns, as seen in RCTs of programs that provide business training in addition to cash transfers and/or require recipients to propose business plans.

Evidence from two studies of unrestricted wealth transfers

Here we provide more detail on two studies which provided unrestricted cash grants to recipients in Uganda, the Youth Opportunities Program (YOP) (evaluated by Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013) and the Women’s Income Generating Support (WINGS) Program (evaluated by Blattman et al 2013). We discuss these programs in detail because they are the best evidence, other than the RCT of GiveDirectly's program, of the effects of unrestricted wealth transfers to individuals. However, both program differ from GiveDirectly's in key ways including their features that encourage recipients to invest their transfers.

The Youth Opportunities Program in Northern Uganda

How the program worked
In YOP, groups of 10 to 40 young adults aged 16-35 applied for cash grants so that their members could enter skilled trades.154 In general, participants were “young, rural, poor, credit constrained, and underemployed.”155 Groups submitted written proposals and could request up to $1,000 for non-agricultural skills training and start up costs.156 Cash was transferred to bank accounts in the name of treatment groups’ management committees and no restrictions were placed on the money’s use.157 The size of the grants varied widely; the average grant was $382 per capita and 80% of grants were between $200 and $600 per capita.158

How did YOP recipients spend the transfers?

Most groups chose one trade and chose to have all members enter that trade.159 Strong evidence suggests that participants invested a large majority of their funds. At the median, treatment group members estimated that their group and fellow members spent 11% on skills training, 52% on tools, 13% on materials, and 24% shared in cash or spent on other things.160 When asked about their own investments two years after the distribution, treatment group members reported 340 more hours of vocational training than controls, most of which was in tailoring, carpentry, metalwork, or hairstyling.161 On average, treatment group members also reported $219 more in business assets than controls two years after the disbursement, although this difference was reduced to $130 after four years.162

What were the overall effects of YOP?

  • Labor supply. Program participants worked 4.1 more hours per week than controls in 2010 and 5.5 more hours per week in 2012.163 In general, participants increased the hours that they spent working in skilled trades to supplement their agricultural income but continued to spend the same amount of time working in agriculture as controls.164
  • Return on investment. There is fairly strong evidence that YOP participants received large returns on their investments, leading to higher income than controls in the long-run. Members of treatment groups earned $8.50 more per month than controls in 2010 and $10.50 more per month in 2012.165 Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013 estimate that the increased earnings in 2010 and 2013 represent average annual returns on the original grant of 30% and 39% respectively.166 There is no evidence that treatment group members earned more per hour than control group members, so the return probably comes from increased opportunities to do profitable work.167
  • Other impacts. Participation in YOP also lead to increased durable assets, non-durable consumption, and subjective well-being.168 There was no evidence that YOP affected non-economic factors such as kin integration, community participation, community and public good contributions, anti-social behavior, and protest attitudes and participation.169

Limitations

There are some limitations that lead us to exercise caution when applying results from YOP to GiveDirectly’s program.

  • Group structure. The group structure of YOP may have acted as a commitment device, leading recipients to invest a greater portion of their grants than recipients of unconditional transfers directly to individuals, like GiveDirectly.170
  • Application process. Groups had to apply for grants with a proposal for investing in skilled trades.171 Motivated, patient, or talented individuals may have been more likely to apply and less likely to be screened out, which could have increased the propensity to invest or returns on investment.172 The application process could also have led to more investment through a mental accounting mechanism, by framing the grant in terms of business.173
  • Size of grant. YOP grants were, on average, $382 per group member.174 Like GiveDirectly, YOP’s grants are one-time unconditional wealth transfers. However, YOP’s grants are less than 40% of the size of GiveDirectly’s. We do not have a strong intuition about whether this would lead GiveDirectly recipients to invest a larger or smaller portion of their transfers. However, GiveDirectly participants may have lower ROIs if recipients experience diminishing returns on investment.
  • Long-run effects and divestment. Treatment members' increased earnings can only be interpreted as return on investment if they are expected to be maintained in the long-run. There is evidence that some recipients divested from their grant over time, which could mean that earning gains were not permanent.175
  • Demographic limitations. Program participants were mostly young adults.176 The effects on business assets and earnings largely disappear if the data is reweighted to reflect the demographic distribution of the entire population.177

The Women’s Income Generating Support (WINGS) Program in Northern Uganda

How the program worked

Villages in WINGS were randomly assigned to one of two phases.178 Participants assigned to phase one entered WINGS in mid-2009 and received five days of business skills training, a $150 startup grant (once they had a business plan approved), and follow up visits and advice from AVSI staff.179 Half of phase 1 participants were also randomly assigned to receive business networking training.180 An end-line survey in November 2010 allowed Blattman et al 2013 to estimate the medium-term effects of the full WINGS program by comparing phase 1 villages to phase 2 villages (who had not yet entered the program).181

Phase 2 villages (which served as controls during phase 1) entered WINGS in early 2011.182 To disentangle the effects of the cash grants from the effects of follow-up, researchers randomly assigned one-third of these villages to receive no follow-up.183

In all, 1,800 of the most vulnerable 14-30 year olds in 120 villages in two districts were selected by AVSI and community leaders to participate in WINGS’ two phases.184 “[T]he typical WINGS candidate was a young woman between the ages of 20 and 35, with little or no formal education, low income and limited access to credit.”185

How did WINGS recipients spend the transfers?

Over half of all participants proposed selling mixed items in their AVSI-approved business plans.186 The vast majority of other business involved the selling of livestock, fish, and farm products.187

When participants themselves estimated the proportion of the grant they spent on different categories, those recipients who did not receive follow up from AVSI staff reported that 27% of the grant was spent on business, 15% was spent on long-term consumption, 2% was spent on short-term consumption, and 54% was saved.188 However, when recipients were asked to estimate the cash amount that they spent on their businesses, they reported an average of just $14.50 of business expenditures, suggesting that they spent less than 10% of the grant on business expenditures.189

What were the overall effects of WINGS 18 months after the grants were distributed?

Phase 1 and phase 2 villages were surveyed eighteen months after phase 1 villages entered WINGS (and before phase 2 villages entered).

  • Labor supply. Participating in WINGS caused a 61% increase in employment hours, which consisted of a 41% increase in hours spent on subsistence work and a 79% increase in hours spent on market activities.190
  • Earnings and return on investment. After subtracting out the effects of follow-up visits by AVSI staff, we estimate that the other components of WINGS increased beneficiaries’ monthly net earnings by an average of about $4.49/month.191 From these earnings numbers we can estimate a mean monthly return on investment of about 3.0% and a mean annual return on investment of about 35.9% on the original $150 grant.192 These calculations are an overestimate of the return on the grant itself, however, because they include the benefits but not the (quite high) costs of services like business skills training, targeting and disbursement, and (for some recipients) group dynamics training.193 We cannot confidently disentangle the effects of the $150 grant from the effects of the add-on services.
  • Other economic effects. Participation in WINGS increased short-term spending, wealth, and savings.194
  • Inflation, economic externalities, and general equilibrium effects. Researchers surveyed randomly chosen non-participant households in treatment and control villages in order to measure WINGS’ effects on non-participants (who made up 75%-85% of households in treatment villages).195 By going into trade and increasing the supply of scarce goods, WINGS recipients appear to have created slightly lower prices for all village members.196 Evidence suggests that WINGS led to decreased profits for existing microentrepreneurs (through enhanced competition) and increased wages and income for non-participating agricultural workers (through reduced supply of agricultural labor as WINGS participants work less on others households’ plots.197
  • Hostility towards recipients. Overall, recipients report a low level of hostility from their community (such as serious conflicts, insults, harm, or unprovoked aggression), but they do report 38% more hostility than controls.198
  • Health and social impacts. Despite large economic returns, WINGS led to few observable medium-run health and social improvements for participants.199

Limitations
There are some limitations that lead us to exercise caution when applying results from WINGS to GiveDirectly’s program.

  • Business plan requirement. We are unable to determine the extent to which the requirement to have a business plan approved encouraged participants to invest more money at higher returns than they would have in the absence of such a requirement.
  • Disentangling program elements. We are unable to determine the extent to which WINGS’ business skills training and group dynamics training may have contributed to positive outcomes. While we were able to adjust estimated returns to subtract out the effects of follow-up by AVSI workers, doing so also increases our uncertainty about the magnitude of returns.
  • Demographics. WINGS participants were chosen as the most vulnerable members of their communities, while GiveDirectly transfers cash to about 40% of the households in a given village.200 This could lead WINGS to have higher returns than GiveDirectly (if the poorest of the poor have the greatest credit constraints and therefore the greatest returns to capital) or could lead GiveDirectly to have higher returns (if the poorest of the poor have worse spending opportunities or make worse spending decisions).
  • Grant size. WINGS’ grant of $150 is only 15% the size of GiveDirectly’s $1,000 transfers. This could lead to GiveDirectly recipients achieving a higher or lower return on their transfers than WINGS recipients. This difference could also lead to differing effects on inflation and on village-wide economies.
  • Long-run effects and divestment. The longest run effects measured by Blattman et al 2013 were eighteen months. Our return on investment calculations assume that earnings gains sustained over eighteen months are permanent and we would guess that these earnings gains are maintained in the long-term. However, households may gradually divest from their investments, causing temporary earnings gains.
  • Conflicting data on investment spending. Blattman et al 2013 measures investment spending in two ways: 1) by asking grant recipients to estimate the portion of their grant that they spent on business expenditures; and 2) by surveying treatment and control households on their expenditures over the course of a month and comparing investment by treatment households against investment by controls.201 These methods result in very different estimates of investment spending, which leave us very uncertain about the proportion of grants that were invested and also decrease our certainty in the reliability of the study’s (self-reported) survey data on the whole.
  • Incomplete description of methodology. Blattman et al 2013 is a policy brief and does not contain the complete methodological description that we would ideally like to see in order to evaluate a study. For example, the study does not describe how data on participants’ net earnings or savings are measured. We believe that accurately measuring earnings and savings among the very poor is difficult so our uncertainty about this data somewhat reduces our confidence in our ROI estimates.

Our interpretation of studies of unconditional wealth transfers with features encouraging investment

Together, Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013 and Blattman et al 2013 provide strong evidence that cash grants of about $150 to $600 to groups of poor applicants and to very poor, uneducated women with business training and business plans can lead to high returns in the medium-term. Blattman et al 2013 also provides some of the most relevant evidence we’ve seen suggesting that hostility from neighbors is not a major problem for most recipients of cash transfers, that cash transfers do not cause inflation, and that cash transfers may have negative effects on neighboring microenterprises.

However, Haushofer and Shapiro 2013’s evaluation of GiveDirectly itself found much smaller returns. We believe that some combination of GiveDirectly’s lack of a business plan requirement, lack of business skills training, and broader age-range of participants is the best explanation for the apparently lower returns earned by its participants. However, it is also possible that the failure to find investment returns was caused by the shorter time horizon of Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 and GiveDirectly participants’ investments may still mature.

Cost-effectiveness of cash transfers

We have not conducted a cost-effectiveness analysis that attempts to quantify the benefits of cash transfers in humanitarian terms. Instead, we have attempted to monetize some of the benefits of the latter, in particular the “developmental effects” of deworming and bednets. (In the case of the comparison with bednets, for instance, this means quantifying the estimated impact of bednets on later-in-life income of children, through a comparison with the effects of deworming, and then subjectively comparing the cost per life saved with the value of that amount of money as a cash transfer.)

In practice, these calculations are highly sensitive to assumptions, especially regarding:

  • the investment returns to cash transfers;
  • how much confidence one places in the developmental impacts of deworming based on limited evidence; and
  • the subjective assessment of the relative value of averting child mortality and improving incomes for adults.

We combine these in a cost-effectiveness model using inputs provided by GiveWell staff members. We estimate that cash transfer programs are in the same range of cost-effectiveness as our other priority programs.

For more, see our Excel model here.

We encourage readers who find formal cost-effectiveness analysis important to examine the details of our calculations and assumptions, and to try putting in their own. To the extent that we have intuitive preferences and biases, these could easily be creeping into the assumption- and judgment-call-laden work we’ve done in generating our cost-effectiveness figures, and we’re not entirely confident that the figures themselves are adding substantial information beyond the intuitions we have from examining the details of them.

Recommendations and concerns

What are the potential downsides of the intervention?

There are a few potential adverse effects of cash transfers:

  • Inflation: a sudden injection of cash into an area may cause inflation. We reviewed four randomized controlled trials investigating this issue:
    • In Programa de Apoyo Alimentario, an un-monitored conditional cash transfer program, no significant effect on inflation was found. The researchers used surveys of stores and households to measure prices of goods at baseline and one year after cash transfers began.202 The reported prices were 2.7% higher in villages receiving cash transfers than in control villages after one year, though the increases were not statistically significant.203 We do not have a clear understanding of how the authors picked the prices they reported from the larger universe of prices they collected.204
    • A randomized study of the Oportunidades conditional cash transfer program finds small increases in prices of 5 of 36 food items for sale in treatment villages immediately following deployment of the cash transfers.205 Although the authors do not observe meaningful increases in prices, they do find positive externalities of cash transfers on ineligible families in treatment villages, equivalent to ~10% of consumption (which is about 2/3 of the benefits experienced by the eligible families in the treatment villages).206
    • Blattman et al 2013, the study of WINGS in Uganda, found evidence of a slight decrease in village-wide prices.207
    • Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, the study of a variant of GiveDirectly's program, found no evidence of village-wide impacts on prices, but estimates are imprecise and may not rule out the possibility of substantial inflation.208
  • Cash transfers could discourage wage-earning work by adults. If adults can control the distribution of their work and leisure time, cash transfers may lead them to substitute some leisure for work, leading to a decrease in wages earned (but most likely not a decrease in overall income). A World Bank review of the evidence on cash transfers (which we have not vetted) examines this question and concludes that transfers "appear to have had, at most, modest disincentives for adult work"; it discusses 5 studies, of which 4 found no impact along this dimension.209

    Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013 and Blattman et al 2013 both found that cash transfers with features encouraging investment increased hours worked by recipients.210 Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, the study of a variant of GiveDirectly's program, found evidence of a $17/month increase in recipients' total revenue, which suggests that did not decrease their hours worked.211

    Note that there is substantially more evidence suggesting that conditional cash transfer programs lead to reductions in child labor,212 which may help explain the gap between transfer sizes and observed increases in consumption.213

  • Giving cash to some and not others could possibly cause social unrest. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, the RCT of a variant of GiveDirectly's program, found no significant effects of transfers on the rate of crime in treatment villages214 or on instances of physical, sexual, or emotional violence in treatment households as compared to control households in treatment villages.215 In Blattman et al 2013, recipients reported a low level of hostility from their community (such as serious conflicts, insults, harm, or unprovoked aggression), but they do report 38% more hostility than controls.216 We have not seen any other rigorous evidence discussing this issue.
  • Diversion of transfers to wealthier individuals. It’s not clear to us whether this problem would be more or less of an issue in the case of cash transfers than in-kind transfers, and we would guess that the extent of the problem depends heavily on the method of making transfers. Our review of GiveDirectly discusses the extent to which this appears to have been a problem in their distributions.

What versions of the intervention are best?

We have reviewed one RCT comparing physical cash transfers with electronic transfers to a recipient's cell phone.217 The study found that transferring money to cell phones was cheaper than transferring physical cash to individuals, though the initial cost of the cell phones made the cell phone transfer more expensive than handing out cash. Had the study continued longer, the cheaper ongoing costs of the cell phone transfer mechanism would have made up for the higher initial costs.218 The study also finds that recipients of the cell phone transfer recipients had to walk less than 25% as far, on average, as those who received physical cash in order to “cash out” their transfers (0.9 vs. 4.04 km).219 The cell phone transfers also appear to have increased the diversity of crops grown and consumed by people who received them, relative to the “placebo” group that just received physical transfers and a cell phone.220 The study did not find any adverse effects of using cell phone transfers relative to handing out physical cash.

Our process

2012

Initially, we conducted searches on JSTOR and Google Scholar for terms related to cash transfers, especially seeking out systematic reviews, and tracing citations in order to find randomized trials.

We relied particularly heavily on two major literature reviews in our research on CCTs: a World Bank review221 and a Cochrane review.222 Of the literature reviews that we found, we relied on these two because they included a high percentage of RCTs and they presented the data from the studies clearly.

We also searched the World Bank DIME database for relevant studies, discussed with GiveDirectly staff, and added studies as they arose in the process of drafting and updating this report.

2013

Many new studies on cash transfers have been published since December 2012. For this update we have not attempted to thoroughly read all new research published on cash transfers over the course of the last year. We focused on a recently released RCT of a variation on GiveDirectly’s program in Kenya.223

We also looked for RCTs with evidence on programs that were unconditional, large, wealth transfers (the approach taken by GiveDirectly) and research that appeared most likely to affect our views of the evidence for this intervention.

We relied heavily on studies and commentary on cash transfers that were sent to us by people who follow GiveWell. We also looked at the abstracts of studies cited by two papers by Chris Blattman224 , which reported results from experiments involving large, unconditional cash transfers.

In addition, we searched Google Scholar for studies with “cash transfers” in the title from 2011-2013. We listed all randomized controlled trials (RCTs) of cash transfers in a spreadsheet and read the abstract for all studies to try to identify studies that might change our views on the intervention. We also looked for evidence on the propensity to invest cash transfers, returns to investment, inflation, economic effects on non-recipients, spending on alcohol and tobacco, and community resentment or hostility toward recipients.

Changes in our views

In general, the additional evidence we reviewed did not substantively change our assessment of the impact of cash transfers. We found little evidence that cash transfers caused inflation, negative economic effects on non-recipients, recipient spending on alcohol and tobacco, and community resentment or hostility toward recipients.

The most significant updates to the evidence are results from a randomized controlled trial of a variant of GiveDirectly's program in Western Kenya. These results are broadly consistent with results measured in other cash transfer programs, but do suggest that GiveDirectly recipients may earn lower investment returns on their transfers than recipients in previously studied cash transfer programs.

These results are particularly significant because they assess GiveDirectly's program itself. We continue to interpret other evidence for cash transfers cautiously, as most research examines programs that differ from GiveDirectly in that: 1) the transfers are conditional or framed heavily in terms of investment; 2) the transfers are 60% to 90% smaller than GiveDirectly’s; 3) trainings or other services are provided alongside the transfers. We are not aware of any other studies of the propensity to invest large wealth transfers that were not framed as business grants, restricted to participants with investment proposals and/or provided alongside some form of business training or technical assistance.

Studies we considered

A list of the studies reviewed for our initial report in 2012 is available above. A list of the research on cash transfers that we have seen since December 2012 is available at this footnote.225

This list includes all new RCTs we have seen but does not attempt to comprehensively list every non-RCT that has been published, instead focusing on studies most likely to affect our views.

Sources

Document Source
Aker et al. 2011 Source
Angelucci and De Giorgi 2009 Source (archive)
Attanasio, Kugler, and Meghir 2008 Source (archive)
Baird et al. 2009 Source
Baird, McIntosh, and Ozler 2011 Source
Blattman et al 2013 Source (archive)
Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013 Source (archive)
Carolina Toth, Field Director of GiveDirectly, email to GiveWell, October 24, 2013 Unpublished
Cunha 2011 Source
Cunha, De Giorgi and Jayachandran 2011 Source
de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008 Source (archive)
de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2012 Unpublished
Edmonds and Schady 2011 Source
Fafchamps et al. 2011 Source (archive)
Fiszbein and Schady 2009 Source
Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012 Unpublished
GiveDirectly Survey for Randomized Controlled Trial Source
Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 Source (archive)
Joahnnes Haushofer, co-author of GiveDirectly RCT, email to GiveWell, November 4, 2013 Unpublished
Lagarde, Haines, and Palmer. 2009 Source (archive)
Macours, Schady, and Vakis 2008 Source
Maluccio 2010 Unpublished
Maluccio and Flores 2005 Source
McKenzie and Woodruff 2008 Source (archive)
Skoufias, Unar, and González-Cossío 2008 Source
The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team. The impact of the Kenya Cash Transfer Program for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on household spending Source (archive)
The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team. The impact of the Kenya Cash Transfer Program for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on human capital Source (archive)
Yablonski and O’Donnell 2009 Source

Supplemental sources

Document Source
Adato, Michelle and Lucy Bassett. 2008. What is the potential of cash transfers to strengthen families affected by HIV and AIDS? A review of the evidence on impacts and key policy debates Source
Aguero, Jorge M., Michael R. Carter, and Ingrid Woolard. 2009. The impact of unconditional cash transfers on nutrition: The South African child support grant Source
Baird, Sarah, Jacobus de Hoop, and Berk Ozler. 2011. Income shocks and adolescent mental health Source
Baird, Sarah et al. 2012. Effect of a cash transfer programme for schooling on prevalence of HIV and herpes simplex type 2 in Malawi: a cluster randomised trial Unpublished
Department for International Development. 2011. Cash transfers Source
Duflo, Esther. 2003. Grandmothers and granddaughters: Old age pensions and intrahousehold allocation in South Africa Unpublished
Jaspars, Susanne and Paul Harvey. 2007. A review of UNICEF’s role in cash transfers to emergency affected populations Source
Oosterbeek, Hessel, Juan Ponce, and Norbert Schady. 2008. The impact of cash transfers on school enrollment: Evidence from Ecuador Source
Paxson, Christina and Norbert Schady. 2007. Does money matter? The effects of cash transfers on child health and development in rural Ecuador Source
Schady, Norbert and Jose Rosero. 2007. Are cash transfers made to women spent like other sources of income? Source
Woolard, Ingrid and Murray Leibbrandt. 2010. The evolution and impact of unconditional cash transfers in South Africa Source
  • 1

    See Bono de Desarrollo Humano (BDH) and Programa Apoyo Alimentario in the programs table below.

  • 2

    The only program with an RCT that we know about which we left out is a program which gives cash to recipients for going to get the results of HIV tests. See Lagarde, Haines, and Palmer. 2009, Pg 17. The amounts involved were small ($1-$3), so we think this is better understood as “payment for picking up results” than as a kind of cash transfer program.

  • 3

    The file is available here.

    This list includes all new RCTs we have seen but does not attempt to comprehensively list every non-RCT that has been published, instead focusing on studies most likely to affect our views.

    The file is broken into three worksheets. "Main set of RCTs" includes the recent studies that have most influenced our views about cash transfers. This sheet primarily consists of studies that clearly contained evidence of: 1) propensity to invest cash transfers; 2) propensity to spend cash transfers on alcohol, tobacco, or other "temptation goods; 3) recipients' returns on investment; 4) hostility or resentment from cash transfers; 5) effects on inflation or village economies, or other economic effects on non-recipients; 6) differing effects between UCTs and CCTs.

    “Useful non-RCTs and comments” includes relevant non-randomized studies, blog posts or commentary.

    “Other results from Google Scholar” contains information from other recent studies of cash transfers that did not strongly affect our overall views. Most of these studies fall into one of a few categories:

    • non-randomized
    • re-analyses of existing data that focus on various potential secondary benefits or costs of cash transfers. There is widely accessible data relevant to some of the biggest public cash transfer programs, leading researchers to test for effects on a very large number of outcomes that were not pre-registered. For example, we have recently seen studies of Progresa/Oportunidades's effects on elderly mortality and child development. We believe that this type of study is more likely to be affected by publication bias/data mining, so we have not carefull reviewed them.
    • studies of CCTs whose results we would not expect to hold for UCTs (primarily studies that report outcomes that are directly related to the conditions placed on recipients).

  • 4Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 268.
  • 5“Conditions:
    • Health
      • Compliance by all household members with the required number of preventive medical checkups.
      • Attendance of family member older than 15 years at health and nutrition lectures.
    • Education
      • School enrollment and minimum attendance rate of 80% monthly and 93% annually.
      • Completion of middle school.
      • Completion of grade 12 before age 22.”

    Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 268.

  • 6

    Transfers represent 20% of baseline per capita expenditures (a measure of consumption) amongst beneficiaries.
    Fiszbein and Schady 2009 2009, Pg 19. Elsewhere, Fiszbein and Schady report figures for Oportunidades as high as 33% and notes, "The transfer amounts as a proportion of per capita expenditures (or consumption) are not the same across all tables in the report because of differences in the surveys used, including their coverage and year." Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 110.

  • 7

    Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 212.

  • 8Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 264.
  • 9“Conditions:
    • Health: Compliance with required frequency of health center visits; compliance enforced only in the 4 departments where PRAF is supported by the IDB; in the remaining 13 departments, households are encouraged only to send children to school/take them for health visit.
    • Education
      • School enrollment
      • Regular school attendance of at least 85%.”

    Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 264

  • 10Transfers represent 9% of baseline per capita expenditures (a measure of consumption) amongst beneficiaries. Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 19.
  • 11Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 212.
  • 12 Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 272.
  • 13 “Conditions:
    • Health
      • "Bimonthly health education workshops (all households).
      • Attendance at prescheduled health care visits every month (aged 0–2) or bimonthly (aged 3–5), adequate weight gain and up-to-date vaccinations (aged 0–5) for all households with children aged 0–5.
    • Education
      • Enrollment in grades 1–4 for children aged 7–13
      • Regular attendance of 85% (that is, no more than 5 absences without valid excuse every 2 months)
      • Grade promotion at end of school year.”

    Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 272.

  • 14Transfers represent 27% of baseline per capita expenditures (a measure of consumption) amongst beneficiaries. Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 20.
  • 15 Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 212.
  • 16Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 270.
  • 17“Conditions:
    • Education
      • Enrollment in grades 1–6 for children aged 7–15
      • Regular attendance of 85%, (that is, no more than 5 absences without valid excuse every 2 months)
      • Deliver teacher transfer to teacher.
    • Other
      • For occupational training: household needed to decide on member who takes course, and payment is conditional on attendance at course.
      • For the business grant: business plan approved by technical team in the Ministry of Family”

    Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 270.

  • 18Transfers represent 18% of baseline per capita expenditures (a measure of consumption) amongst beneficiaries. Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 20.
  • 19Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 212.
  • 20Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 258.
  • 21 “Conditions:
    • Health
      • Children aged 0–5: bimonthly visits to health posts for growth and development checkups and immunizations.
    • Education
      • School enrollment for children aged 6–15
      • School attendance at least 90% of school days
      • Must be enrolled in school and have attendance at basic education classes of at least 80% (including both justified and unjustified absences).”

    Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 258.

  • 22 Transfers represent 10% of baseline per capita expenditures (a measure of consumption) amongst beneficiaries. Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 19.
  • 23Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 212.
  • 24Dates not listed in study. Skoufias, Unar, and González-Cossío 2008
  • 25

    "Localities were randomly assigned into three treatment groups and one control group. Two of the treatment groups were assigned to receive food transfers with and without receiving a health and nutrition education package, and a third to a cash transfer of equal value to the food basket plus the education package...The PAL program offers nutrition and health education sessions (platicas), as well as participation in program-related logistic activities. However, given that attendance of the platicas is not a requirement for the receipt of the benefits, the PAL program is essentially an unconditional transfer program...” Skoufias, Unar, and González-Cossío 2008, Pgs 8-9.

  • 26

    Skoufias, Unar, and González-Cossío 2008, Pg 15.

  • 27“Both the in-kind and cash transfers were, in practice, delivered bimonthly, two monthly allotments at a time per household. The transfer size was the same for every eligible house- hold regardless of family size. Resale of in-kind food transfers was not prohibited, nor were there purchase requirements attached to the cash transfers. As mentioned above, the monthly box of food had a market value of about 206 pesos in the program villages, and the cash transfer was 150 pesos per month, based on the government’s wholesale cost of procuring the in-kind items.” Cunha, De Giorgi and Jayachandran 2011. Pg 13.
  • 28

    Baird, McIntosh, and Ozler 2011.

  • 29
    • “Monthly school attendance for all girls in the CCT arm was checked and payment for the following month was withheld for any student whose attendance was below 80% of the number of days school was in session for the previous month.” Baird, McIntosh, and Ozler 2011, Pg 9.
    • “In the UCT EAs, the offers were identical with one crucial difference: there was no requirement to attend school to receive the monthly cash transfers.” Baird, McIntosh, and Ozler 2011, Pg 9.

  • 30

    “The average offer to the households consisted of $10/month – for a total of $100 for the school year transferred in equal amounts for 10 months. $10/month represents roughly 15% of total monthly household consumption in our sample households at baseline, which places this program in the middle-to-high end of the range of relative transfer sizes for conditional cash transfer programs elsewhere.” Baird et al. 2009, Pg 12.

  • 31

    “The cash payments take place monthly at centrally located and well-known places, such as churches and schools.” Baird et al. 2009, Pg 13.

  • 32

    The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team. The impact of the Kenya Cash Transfer Program for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on human capital.

  • 33

    “Total adjusted mean monthly spending is Ksh 1442 at baseline among T households, or approximately US$18 per month and 60 US cents per day per adult equivalent. Although total adjusted expenditures are similar across T and C households at baseline, the value among T households at follow-up is about Ksh 253 greater – this is consistent with the size of the transfer, which averages Ksh 300 per household in 2007 Ksh.” The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team. The impact of the Kenya Cash Transfer Program for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on household spending, pg 14. 300/1442 = 20.8%

  • 34“Eligible households, those who are ultra-poor and contain an OVC, receive a flat monthly transfer of US$21 (this was increased in the 2011/12 budget from Ksh 1500 to Ksh 2000).” The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team. The impact of the Kenya Cash Transfer Program for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on household spending Pg 11.
  • 35

  • 36

    “Cash treatments were given without restrictions. Those receiving cash were told that they could purchase anything they wanted, whether for their business or for other purposes. In reality, the grant was destined to be unrestricted because we lacked the ability to monitor what recipients did with the funds, and because cash is fungible. Being explicit about this was intended to produce more honest reporting regarding use of the funds.” de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008 Pg 1337.

  • 37

    Mean grant as a percentage of mean annual business profit. Mean grant was 15,000 LKR; mean real profits in March 2005 were 3,851 LKR (de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008, Table 1). 15,000/(12*3851) = 32.46%.

  • 38

    “Firms were told before the initial survey that we would survey them quarterly for five periods, and that after the first wave of the survey, we would conduct a random prize drawing, with prizes of equipment for the business or cash. The random drawing was framed as compensation for participating in the survey. We indicated to the owners that they would receive at most one grant. For logistical reasons, we distributed just over half the prizes awarded after the first wave of the survey, and the remaining prizes after the third wave; enterprises not given a prize after the first wave were not told whether or not they had won one of the prizes to be awarded in the second distribution until after the third wave. The prize consisted of one of four grants: 10,000 LKR (∼US$100) of equipment or inventories for their business, 20,000 LKR in equip- ment/inventories, 10,000 LKR in cash, or 20,000 LKR in cash. In the case of the in-kind grants, the equipment was selected by the enterprise owner and purchased by our research assistants.5 Subsequently, we received funding to extend the panel to nine waves. Because this represented an extension of the survey rela- tive to what firms were told before the baseline survey, we granted each of the untreated firms 2,500 LKR (~US$25) after the fifth wave. The randomization was stratified within district (Kalutara, Galle, and Matara) and zone (unaffected and indirectly affected by the tsunami). Allocation to treatment was done ex ante among the 408 firms kept in the sample after the baseline survey.6 A total of 124 firms received a treatment after wave 1, with 84 receiving a 10,000-LKR treatment and 40 receiving a 20,000-LKR treatment. Another 104 firms were selected at random to receive a treatment after the third survey wave: 62 receiving the 10,000-LKR treat- ment and 42 the 20,000-LKR treatment. In each case, half the firms receiving a treatment amount received cash, and the other half equipment.” de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008.. Pgs 1335-1336.

  • 39

    Fafchamps et al. 2011.

  • 40

    Mean grant as a percentage of mean annual business profit. Mean grant was 150 cedis; mean profits in the trimmed sample at baseline are 106 cedis per month (= (103+99+115)/3) (Fafchamps et al. 2011 Table 1). 150/(12*106) = 11.83%.

  • 41

    “We also randomly selected when firms would receive their grant, staggering the timing of the grants, so that 198 firms were assigned to receive the grants after the second round, a further 181 firms assigned to receive the grants after the third round, and 18 firms were assigned to receive the grants after the fourth round. This staggering was done both for the purpose of managing the logistics of making these grants, and to provide incentives for firms to remain in the study for multiple rounds since they were told more grants would be given out after rounds 3 and 4. These grants were framed to firms as prizes to thank firms for participating in the survey. Participants in the survey were told that we were undertaking a study of small firms in Ghana, and that some of the firms would be randomly chosen to receive prizes as a token of our appreciation for their participation in the survey. Firms which were selected in either treatment group were not told they had been selected for a prize until the time their prize was being given out.” Fafchamps et al. 2011. Pg 16.

  • 42

    McKenzie and Woodruff 2008.

  • 43

    “Cash was given without restrictions on its use. Owners were allowed to contribute funds of their own to purchase items costing more than 1,500 pesos (in practice none did).” McKenzie and Woodruff 2008. Pg 467.

  • 44

    Mean grant as a percentage of mean annual business profit. Grants are 1,500 pesos; mean baseline profits are 3,373 pesos per month (= (3433+3312)/2) (McKenzie and Woodruff 2008 Table 2). 1500/(12*3373) = 3.71%

  • 45

    “Before the first round of the survey, firms were told that the only compensation that they would receive for participating was a chance of receiving either cash or capital through prizes to be given after each survey round.6 The prize was a grant of 1,500 pesos (about $140). After the first round of the survey, a single draw from a computerized random number generator was used to randomly assign firms to treatment and control groups.7 Among the firms assigned to treatment status, the random draw also determined the round in which they would be treated and whether they would receive their grant as cash or capital for their enterprise. The results of the initial random draw were not revealed to either the survey company or the firms in the sample. After each round, the survey company was given a list of firms to which to distribute the grants. Each firm could receive a prize at most once, although this was not made explicit to the firms.” McKenzie and Woodruff 2008. Pg 466.

  • 46

    Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 16.

  • 47

    "The increase in expenditures on food generally is directed toward increasing quality. Households that benefi ted from Familias en Acción in Colombia signifi cantly increased items rich in protein, such as milk, meat, and eggs (Attanasio and Mesnard 2006); and the increases in food expenditures in Mexico and Nicaragua were driven largely by increased consumption of meat, fruits, and vegetables (Hoddinott, Skoufias, and Washburn 2000; [Maluccio and Flores 2005]). Oportunidades also increased caloric diversity as measured by the number of different food-stuffs consumed. At similar overall food expenditure levels in Nicaragua, [Macours, Schady, and Vakis 2008] shows that households that receive transfers from the Atención a Crisis program spend significantly less on staples (primarily rice, beans, and tortillas) and significantly more on animal protein (chicken, meat, milk, and eggs), as well as on fruits and vegetables [Angelucci and De Giorgi 2009] and [Attanasio, Kugler, and Meghir 2008] report similar results using data for urban Oportunidades in Mexico. Not only did households diversify their diets; they also shifted toward higher-quality sources of calories." Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pg 113.

  • 48

    Angelucci and De Giorgi 2009. Table 1, Pg 30. May 1999 treatment effect is 24 pesos of additional food per adult equivalent. This amounts to roughly three quarters of the mean transfer: “The actual monthly grants up to November 1999 are sizeable, averaging 200 pesos per household, or 32.5 pesos per adult equivalent.” Pg 6.

  • 49

    Mean 4.07 adult equivalents per household (Cunha 2011, Table 2. Pg 37). Cash transfers 150 pesos per month (Cunha 2011. Pg 10). Cash transfers are estimated to increase food consumption by 34.72 pesos per adult equivalent per month (Cunha 2011 Table 4. Pg 39). 4.07*34.72/(150)= 94%.

  • 50

    “Over the 2 years, the actual average monetary transfer (excluding the teacher transfer) was approximately C$3,500 (US$272 or 17 percent of total annual household expenditures).” Pg 8. Estimated impacts on total spending at the household level are 2,817 Cordoba (Table 4.1, Pg 27), or 80% of the transfer. The mean per capita increase in total household expenditures is 686 Cordoba (Table 4.2, Pg 29), and the mean per capita increase in total food expenditure is 640 Cordoba (Table 4.3, Pg 30), or 93% of the increase in spending. 93%*80% = 75%. Maluccio and Flores 2005

  • 51

    The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team. The impact of the Kenya Cash Transfer Program for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on household spending,

    • “[T]he size of the transfer... averages Ksh 300 per household in 2007 Ksh.” Pg 14.
    • “Results from this estimation of programme impacts, without con- trolling for the change in total expenditure induced by the programme, are shown in the odd-numbered columns in Table 2, Panel A. These show statistically significant impacts of the programme expenditures for food (Ksh 145), health (Ksh 39), and clothing (Ksh 25).” Pg 16.
    • 145/300 = 48%

  • 52
    • “For alcohol consumption, while both [in-kind and cash transfer] treatments induced statistically significant increases (1.73 pesos per [adult equivalent] under in-kind transfers and 2.89 under cash) they are also indistinguishable from each other.” Cunha 2011, Pg 22.
    • For tobacco, see Cunha 2011, Table 5.
    • The total cash transfer equivalent is 193 pesos, so to estimate the increase in alcohol consumption as a portion of the transfer we take 2.89/193 = 1.5%. See Cunha 2011, Pgs 14-15.

  • 53

    Cunha 2011, Pg 22. In particular, as indicated above, food consumption was reported to increase by 94% of the total transfer amount.

  • 54

    Maluccio and Flores 2005, Pg 32. Table 4.5.

  • 55

    Maluccio and Flores 2005, Pg 32.

  • 56

    The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team. The impact of the Kenya Cash Transfer Program for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on household spending, Pg 13. Alcohol and tobacco consumption goes from .4% of consumption at baseline to .2% at follow-up in the treatment group, while going from .3% to .2% in the control group so the cash transfers are actually estimated to reduce alcohol and tobacco consumption, though the estimate is not statistically significant. (This is not due to an overall increase in consumption; the same pattern holds in absolute currency terms.)

  • 57

    Three possible forms of misreporting would have different effects:

    • Simple linear underestimates: if everyone under-reported alcohol consumption by a fixed amount (e.g. $1), then the estimated effect of transfers on alcohol consumption would be unbiased, though they would be upward-biased as a proportion of baseline alcohol consumption.
    • Simple geometric underestimates: if everyone underreported alcohol consumption by a certain proportion (e.g. half), then absolute estimates of the impact of cash transfers on alcohol consumption (including the estimate that 1.5% of transfers were spent on alcohol in the Programa de Apoyo Alimentario food security program in Mexico) would be biased downwards. The estimated proportional increase (e.g. recipients of transfers spent twice as much on alcohol as the control group) would likely continue to be unbiased. This strikes us as the most likely form of measurement error.
    • Transfer recipients underestimate asymmetrically: if transfer recipients recognize that a study is attempting to measure the impact of their transfers on alcohol consumption and therefore lie about alcohol consumption while the control group is truthful, then the estimates would be biased downward in unpredictable ways.

  • 58

    "We test this hypothesis using data from a controlled randomized experiment of the Oportunidades CCT program in Mexico. We find that beneficiary households increased ownership of productive farm assets, such as farm animals and land for agricultural production, significantly faster than nonbeneficiary households; that agri -cultural production in terms of both crops and animal products increased faster for beneficiary households than nonbeneficiary households; and that this resulted in sig -nificantly higher agricultural income. In fact, we estimate that an 18-month exposure to the program resulted in a 9.6 percent increase in agricultural income. Beneficiary households also started substantially more nonagricultural microenterprises, mainly production of handcrafts for sale, compared to nonbeneficiary households … We then explore whether returns on these investments persist over time and raise long-term living standards as measured by consumption. We find that even 4 years after households in the control group were incorporated into the program, consumption levels for the original treatment households were 5.6 percent higher than for the original control households. This result suggests that returns on investments made by treatment households during the initial 18-month experimental period did in fact translate into improvements in long-term living standards." Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012, Pg 2.

  • 59

    In this case, investment is defined as anything that is not consumed in the current period. Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012. Pg 183. “In this section, we estimate how much of the transfer is consumed versus invested—i.e., the marginal propensity to consume (MPC), and the return on transfers in terms of long-term consumption via the investment pathway, which we call the marginal investment effect (MIE). The MPC and the MIE characterize two principal pathways through which transfers affect living standards. First, households can increase living standards in the short run by spending part of the current cash transfer. This amount is just the marginal propensity to consume transfers. Transfers not consumed are saved or invested, so that the marginal propensity to invest transfers is equivalent to (1–MPC).” It is not clear from the paper whether investment in household improvement, such a purchasing a new roof, is considered consumption or investment.

  • 60

    Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012, pg 189.

  • 61

    Investment in this context is defined as both in terms of specific spending activites (e.g. related to agriculture, home business, and durable goods) and as anything not consumed in the current period; both find limited to no effects:

    • “The study also asked about other forms of expenditures related to investments at the household level, such as on household improvements, durable goods, and so forth; none of these showed significant changes. Finally, we examine expenditures on other specific non-food items including books, furniture, child clothing, remittances sent, lotteries, and parties, and find no significant program effects. Naturally, since total expenditures were flat while the percentage spent on food remained the same, it was unlikely that investments or expenditures like these would have changed very much. It is important to emphasize that the evidence indicates that households are indeed following the recommendations of the program; that is, they are spending most of their income from the program on current (food and education) expenditures. (35) This finding is somewhat weaker in the second year, however, where increased expenditures appear to be slightly smaller than the transfers. It is possible that any differences are relected in increased savings (or increased leisure, discussed later), although we do not have the information to verify this.” The footnote says, “(35) Information on savings is not available so it is not possible to assess whether there was increased savings. Given the evidence on expenditures relative to the transfer size, however, any such increase was likely to be small.” Maluccio and Flores 2005 pgs 32-33.
    • “In years when transfers were being given, the programme increased expendi- tures, and the lion’s share of the increase was on food and educational expenditures. These findings are consistent with the programme’s orientation toward increasing current expenditures (one of its three key objectives) and the required conditions, as well as with evidence from a variety of settings that resources in the hands of women are more likely to be directed to these types of expenditures. With those findings, I turned to an assessment of the programme on investment of various types. Overall, there was only limited evidence that the programme led to increases in the agricultural and non-agricultural types of investment considered. These results are corroborated by a separate analysis estimating a consumption equation, which demonstrated that even though the transfers were to last only for three years and thus were transitory, the average MPC out of transfers was approximately one. Moreover, cumulative past transfers had no effect on current expenditures.
      The findings do not imply that the programme had no long-term effects – it very likely did via increased investment in child health and education, which should continue to lead to benefits for many years to come. In contrast to PROGRESA in Mexico, where there seems to have been substantial agricultural investment and returns from it (Gertler et al., 2007; Todd et al., 2010), there is only weak evidence that RPS increased these other investments in the rural localities in which it operated.” Maluccio 2010, Pgs 34-35.

  • 62

    Maluccio and Flores 2005 Pg 33.

  • 63

  • 64

    “The last column in Table 4, Panel A sums up the ex-ante and ex-post effects; the ex-ante effects suggest that about Ksh 7 out of the total transfer is spent on non-consumption expenditures, possibly investments, while the actual impacts suggest a much larger Ksh 40 (or 13 per cent of the transfer value) goes to non-consumption uses.” The Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team. The impact of the Kenya Cash Transfer Program for Orphans and Vulnerable Children on household spending Pg 23.

  • 65

    If, for instance, the treatment and control group systematically underreported spending by a uniform proportion, there would be a gap between the estimated consumption increase and the transfer size of at least that proportion.

  • 66

    “Cash treatments were given without restrictions. Those receiving cash were told that they could purchase anything they wanted, whether for their business or for other purposes. In reality, the grant was destined to be unrestricted because we lacked the ability to monitor what recipients did with the funds, and be- cause cash is fungible. Being explicit about this was intended to produce more honest reporting regarding use of the funds. In the survey subsequent to the treatment, we asked how they had used the treatment. On average, 58% of the cash treatments was invested in the business between the time of the treatment and the subsequent survey. An additional 12% was saved, 6% was used to repay loans, 5% was spent on household consumption, 4% was spent on repairs to the house, 3% was spent on equipment or inventories for another business, and the remaining 12% was spent on “other items.” Of the amount invested in the enterprise, about two-thirds was invested in inventories and the rest in equipment.” McKenzie and Woodruff 2008 Pg 1337.

  • 67

    de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008,online appendix, Table A4. With no trimming of capital stock, grants are found to increase capital stock by more than 100% of their value (107-115%); after trimming the top and bottom 1% of capital stocks, grants are estimated to increase capital stock by 62-87% of their value. “The first column of the table verifies that the treatment did increase capital stock as intended. All four treatments are significantly associated with higher levels of capital stock. The measured impact of the cash treatments is somewhat higher than the impact of the in-kind treatments, though the large standard errors on the individual treatments mean that the differences between cash and in-kind treatments are not significant. Trimming the top and bottom 1% of capital stock reduces these differences.11” Pgs 1341-42. Footnote 11 says: “The treatment effects after trimming capital stock are 5,780 (6,227) for the 10,000 LKR in-kind (cash) treatment and 13,443 (17,325) for the 20,000 LKR in-kind (cash) treatment.”

  • 68

    Fafchamps et al. 2011. “The remaining columns report the estimated impacts on household expenditure, which was collected each wave. Point estimates suggest higher positive impacts on expenditure for those receiving the cash treatments than those getting the in-kind treatment or the control group, especially for women with low initial profits. We see a large and highly significant effect of the cash treatment on total quarterly spending for women as a whole, and for the subgroup of women with low initial profits. The coefficients are huge: women who were given a 150 cedis cash grant are estimated to be spending 120 cedis more a quarter after the grant. The magnitude of this coefficient appears to be driven by a few firm owners reporting very large spending levels — truncating at the 99th percentile of total expenditure lowers this coefficient to 95, and at the 95th percentile lowers it to 76 cedis (which is still significant at the 5% level). For males receiving the cash treatment, the point estimates also suggest large increases in total quarterly spending (with a coefficient of 50 to 73 cedis depending on the level of truncation), but the standard error is so large that we can never reject equality with zero.” Pgs 28-29.

  • 69

    Fafchamps et al. 2011. Table 5, columns 1 and 2, Pg 53. Capital stock for women increased by 49.17-82.61 cedis, while capital stock for men increased by 2.21-31.36 cedis, both on a grant of 150 cedis.

  • 70

    See the Youth Opportunities Program evaluated by Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013 and the Women's Income Generating Support Program evaluated by Blattman et al 2013.

  • 71
    • “Cash transfers increase the likelihood of having an iron roof by 23 percentage points relative to a control group mean of 16%.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 16.
    • “Recipients of large transfers are 23 percentage points more likely to have an iron roof than recipients of small transfers.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 17.
    • “The purchase of an iron roof represents an expenditure of approximately KES 35,220 (USD 402, PPP 564), or 75% of the average transfer value. In addition to a store of value (roofs can be resold), an iron roof potentially provides an investment return to households by obviating the need to periodically replace their thatched roofs, which must be done ever 1 to 2 years, costing approximately KES 4,800 (USD 55, PPP 77) per replacement, implying a simple return on the investment in the roof of between 7 and 14%. Reported savings balances double as a result of cash transfers, but from low initial levels (PPP USD 10).” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 16-17.
    • We have not vetted the methodology used to estimate the return on investment for iron roofs. See Data on roofs for more information.

  • 72
    • Treatment households spent about $13 per month more than control households on business expenses, which were primarily made up of non-durable expenses on non-agricultural businesses. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 33.
    • ”These effects translate into an overall increase in monthly revenues for recipient households, PPP USD 15 higher (including revenues from the sale of animals and meat), but we do not observe a significant increase in estimated profits from self-employment.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 19.
    • According to Table 5, total revenue was about $17 per month higher for treatment than for control groups. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, Table 5.
    • In particular, the RCT found no increase in imputed or self-reported non-agricultural profits. There was a $1.21 per month decrease in farm profits and a $1.68 per month increase in livestock flow profits. Total profits were estimated to decrease by a statistically insignificant $0.16 per month (with a standard error of $3.74). Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 33.

  • 73
    • 30%-39% ROI in YOP. "The 2010 and 2012 earnings ITT estimates in Table III represent ROIs of 30% and 39% on the per capita grant.21 The 2010 and 2012 TOT estimates represent ROIs of 36% and 49%. . . . All these ROIs are large relative to the real commercial lending rates of 10 to 30% common among medium-size firms in Uganda. They also approach the ROIs estimated from cash grants to existing microenterprises in Sri Lanka, Mexico, and Ghana (de Mel et al., 2008; McKenzie and Woodruff, 2008; Udry and Anagol, 2006)." Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 24.
    • 36% ROI in WINGS
      • After subtracting out the effects of follow-up visits by AVSI staff, we estimate that the other components of WINGS increased beneficiaries’ monthly net earnings by an average of about $4.49/month.
        • The full WINGS program (including follow-up) increased beneficiaries’ monthly net earnings by an average of $6.50. “For the average WINGS beneficiary, net cash earnings increased UGX 16,211 in the month before the survey, a 98% increase over controls. . . . In absolute terms, an increase of UGX 16,211 does not seem large (about $6.50 at market exchange rates of 2500). . . . In absolute terms, an increase of UGX 16,211 does not seem large (about $6.50 at market exchange rates of 2500).” Blattman et al 2013, pgs. 14-15.
        • Using data from phase 2 (where some villages were randomly selected to receive no follow-up visits), Blattman et al 2013 estimate that the follow-up component was responsible for about $2.01 per month of the net earnings increase. “Those assigned to any follow-up report 27% higher cash earnings, a statistically significant increase. In absolute terms the impact is small—about 5,000 UGX per month, or USD 2.01. Since cash earnings are so low in this group, however, the relative impact on the business is substantial.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 42.
        • We therefore estimate that WINGS increased beneficiaries’ monthly net earnings by $4.49/month ($6.50-$2.01) after the effects of follow-up are subtracted out. Please note that, even after subtracting out follow-up effects, these participants still benefitted from business skills training, the requirement to create a business plan and (in some cases) business networking training in addition to the $150 grant. We are unable to disentangle the effects of these components of WINGS but would guess that the grant was responsible for most of the earnings increase.
      • From these earnings numbers we can estimate a mean monthly return on investment of about 3.0% and a mean annual return on investment of about 35.9% on the original $150 grant.
        • Our mean monthly return: $4.49/$150 = 3.0%
        • Our mean annual return: 12*$4.49/$150 = 35.9%
        • These calculations assume that the earnings increases observed after 18 months are permanent. We would guess that this assumption is accurate.
        • Assuming (unrealistically but for the sake of argument) that no services other than the grant had any effect and varying other assumptions about time horizon and discount rate, Blattman et al 2013 estimates that the average lifetime ROI on the $150 grant was between 18% and 1,577%. Blattman et al 2013, pg. 30, Table 4.

  • 74

    “We find that household per capita consumption in 2003 is 10.84 pesos higher for original treatment households, and this difference is statistically significant (first column in Table 5). This impact amounts to a 5.6 percent increase in consumption for treatment households, even 4 years after controls started receiving program benefits. While we do not have agricultural production for the 2003 survey round, we do have home-produced consumption. We also find a significant increase in home- produced consumption (significantly different from 0 at the 10 percent level), which is consistent with a sustained increase in agricultural productivity (second column in Table 5).” Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012, pg 179.

  • 75

    “Eligible households in treatment communities began receiving benefits starting in March/April of 1998, while eligible house- holds in control communities were incorporated in November/December of 1999. In order to minimize anticipation effects, households in control communities were not informed that Oportunidades would provide benefits to them until two months before incorporation. Behrman and Todd (1999) confirm that the original randomization balanced the control and treatment communities; and Attanasio, Meghir, and Santiago (forthcoming) explicitly test, but find no evidence of, anticipation effects amongst control households.” Pgs 168-169. This implies that treatment communities received an additional 20 months of transfers relative to control communities.

    Table 8 reports that mean actual transfer per adult equivalent in treatment households in October 1998 was 24.196, in May 1999 was 38.691, and in November 1999 was 31.141. The mean of these values is 31.34. Multiplying by 20, for the number of months that the treatment communities received treatment and the control communities did not, we estimate that treatment caused an average transfer of 627 pesos per adult equivalent in the treatment group before the control group began to be treated.

    Four years later, consumption was 10.84 pesos per adult equivalent per month higher in the treatment group, implying a 1.7% (10.84/627) monthly return. 10.84/627*12 = 20.746%

  • 76

    Table 8 reports that the difference between monthly transfer and increase in consumption was:

    • October 1998: 24.196 – 17.613= 6.583
    • May 1999: 38.691 – 16.033 = 22.658
    • November 1999: 31.141 – 14.596 = 16.545

    This implies a mean savings from transfers of 15.262 per month, or 305.24 over the period of treatment prior to the control group receiving treatment.

    Four years later, consumption was 10.84 pesos per adult equivalent per month higher in the treatment group, implying a 3.6% (10.84/305) monthly return and 42.6% annual return.

  • 77

    Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012:

    • “The second coefficient, ρg. 12 , represents the effect on consumption of transfers made in the second 12-month period prior to the current transfers. This coefficient is positive and significantly different from zero. We estimate that for every peso transferred during this period, current consumption increased by 1.8 cents. The third coefficient represents the effect on consumption of transfers made in the period prior to 24 months before the current transfer period. This coefficient is positive and significantly different from zero, and implies that for every peso transferred during this period, current consumption increased by 1.6 cents. While this coefficient is slightly lower than the second lag, the two are not significantly different from one another, as reported in the sixth row of Table 10 ( p-value = 0.805). This suggests at best a slight drop off in the MIE due to depreciation.
      Using these estimates of MPC and MIE, we run a back-of-the-envelope calculation to predict the long-term effects of the cash transfers on living standards, simply multiplying the MIE by total cumulative transfers. By November 2003, after 51/2 years on the program, households in the treatment group had received a total of 2,624 pesos per capita, on average.28 Using our more conservative estimate of the MIE of 0.016, this implies an increase in consumption of 41.9 pesos per capita per month through the investment pathway. If these increases in consumption are, as argued here, derived from productive investments made by beneficiary households thanks to the cash transfers, then to the extent that the investments are long term, these increases in living standards are expected to be sustained over time even after the household is no longer receiving cash transfers from Oportunidades.” Pg 190.
    • “We estimate the MPC to be 0.74, implying that approximately three-quarters of the transfers are directly consumed and one-quarter are invested. The estimated MPC is significantly different from 1 at conventional significance levels, as the test in the fifth row in Table 6 reports ( p-value = 0.008). We also tested, and could not reject ( p-value of 0.956), the hypothesis that the MPC is the same for all four rounds of the data used (results available upon request).” Pg 189.

  • 78

    19.2% per year / 26% invested = 73.8% annual return on invested funds.
    1.6% per month/ 26% invested = 6.2% monthly return on invested funds.

  • 79

    Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012. “We solve this problem by instrumenting current transfers and past cumulative transfers with the maximum potential current and maximum potential past cumulative transfers, respectively, that a family could achieve if the maximum number of eligible children in the household were enrolled in school.27 At each time t, we compute a family’s maximum potential transfer using a modified version of the formula in (9) and assuming that all eligible children that were enrolled at baseline have advanced a grade per year. Because of the cap on total benefits and because the transfers are zero for the first three years of school, potential transfers are a nonlinear function of the number of children at baseline who could be enrolled in school in period t.
    Maximum potential transfers and the three lagged maximum potential cumulative transfers are likely to be valid instruments for three reasons. First, they are strong predictors of the actual transfers and the three actual cumulative lagged transfer variables. Indeed, and as expected, the distribution of potential transfers follows that of the actual transfers very closely, albeit potential transfers are an overestimate of the actual transfers (given noncompliance, administrative delays in payments, etc.). The simple correlation amongst both variables is 0.89. After controlling for time effects and baseline covariates, 55.7 and 65.9 percent of the variation in current and cumulative lagged transfers are explained by their potential counterparts.
    Second, they are unlikely to be correlated with consumption via other pathways, such as other income sources. Indeed, they are uncorrelated with changes in children’s labor supply due to the program as they are computed assuming that all eligible children enrolled at baseline are still in school and have advanced one school grade per school year. Nonetheless, the transfers could also be taken in leisure by reducing adult labor supply, which would reduce household income and therefore household consumption. Everything else held constant, this would imply a down- ward biased estimate of the MPC. Parker and Skoufias (2000) show that there is no effect of the program on adult labor supply, and we can thus safely assume that the transfer variables are not correlated with other earned sources of income.
    Regarding program impacts on unearned income, the crowding out effect of pri- vate transfers found in Albarran and Attanasio (2005) and discussed earlier, would suggest that our estimated MPC is underestimated. However, private transfers are unlikely to explain our results as the crowding out effects are small in size and, on average, approximately 7.3 percent of eligible households report receiving private transfers over the experimental period (fourth column in Table 6). This proportion doubles to 15.4 percent in November 2003 (see the fifth column in Table 5) suggest- ing that the crowding effects are not sustained over time.
    Finally, there is no bias from omitted family demographic structure as we directly control for family structure in the regression models. In fact, maximum potential transfers are not strongly correlated with the number of children in the household because of the nonlinear allocation rule. Let’s imagine the following extreme situations: a household with three girls in grade 2 of primary school, and a household with three girls in grade 2 of junior high school. Both households have three female children, but while the first household will receive no school transfers, the latter household will receive a large monthly transfer. In addition, families with four or more children in junior high school would receive the same transfer amount as the latter household because the cap on total benefits would be binding. Indeed, the data shows low correlations between transfers and the number of children under 17 (r = 0.14), or with the number of siblings 15–17 years old (r = 0.42), 12–14 years old (r = 0.22), 6–11 years old (r = −0.12), and 0–5 years old (r = −0.10). Thus, we are able to explicitly control for household size and the number of children in the household in the empirical specification, which allows for identification of the potential transfer variable.” Pgs 187-188.

  • 80

    Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012. Table 10, column 2. Pg 189. This implies an 18% annual return on transfers (12*1.5%=18%) and a 35% annual return on investment (12*1.5%/(1-.487)=35.1%).

  • 81

    “One potential concern with this specification is that the current and cumulative transfer amounts that the household actually receives are determined in part by whether children attend school. If a household sends their children to work instead of going to school, then the family would have lower transfers but higher income from the child’s work. This would imply a downward biased estimate of the MPC and an upward biased estimate of the MPI. In reality, this is a concern for our estimates given that Parker and Skoufias (2000) and Skoufias and Parker (2001) find that the program reduces child labor and increases enrollment in junior high (secondary) schools as the opportunity cost of these children being in the labor force is now higher. Schultz (2004) also finds positive effects for primary school and, more notably, junior high school enrollment for boys and girls.” Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012, pg 187.

  • 82

    Gertler, Martinez and Rubio-Codina 2012, table 10, column 1.

  • 83

    Both papers focus on the two-thirds of the initial sample that were not directly affected by the 2004 Indian Ocean Tsunami; including those firms that were affected would increase the estimated returns. The heterogeneity across tsunami-exposed areas is described in column 6 of Table 3 and discussion on page 1347 of de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008.

      In general, the authors selected their sample by picking regions with high-percentage of self-employed workers and low education levels. The authors describe the remainder of the selection process: "The full survey was given to 659 enterprises meeting these criteria. After reviewing the baseline survey data, we eliminated 41 enterprises either because they exceeded the 100,000 LKR maximum size or because a follow-up visit could not verify the existence of an enterprise. The remaining 618 firms constitute the baseline sample. We present results later in the paper indicating that returns to capital were higher among firms directly affected by the tsunami, but we exclude these firms for most of the analysis because the tsunami recovery process might affect returns to capital. We leave the full analysis of the impact of the capital shocks on enterprise recovery to another paper. Excluding the directly affected firms leaves us with a baseline sample of 408 enterprises. The 408 firms are almost evenly split across two broad industry categories, with 203 firms in retail sales and 205 in manufacturing/services. Firms in retail sales are typically small grocery stores. The manufacturing/services firms cover a range of common occupations of microenterprises in Sri Lanka, including sewing clothing, making lace products, making bamboo products, repairing bicycles, and making food products such as hoppers and string hoppers" (de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008, Pgs 1334-1335)

    • 84

      de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2012. “[W]e found long-lasting impacts from one-time grants given in a randomized experiment to subsistence firms. Five years after we gave $100 or $200 to 115 of 197 male and 100 of 190 female Sri Lankan microenterprise owners, we found 10-percentage-point-higher enterprise survival rates, and $8-to-$12-per-month-higher profits for male-owned businesses that received the grants. Female-owned businesses showed no long-term (or short-term) impacts. Our follow-up investigation interviewed 94% of the original sample and collected survivorship data
      from the remaining 6%, demonstrating that tracking long-term outcomes is both feasible and worthwhile.” Abstract.

    • 85

      de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2012. “For males, a 10,000 LKR grant increased monthly profits by 600 to 1200 LKR, a 6 to 12% monthly real return. This persists throughout the time period and does not narrow dramatically (as would be the case with a temporary effect) or increase dramatically (as would be the case if returns compounded). This effect is robust, and strengthened, when we look at labor income and include the labor income for those businesses which have closed, and are shown in SOM text 5 to be robust to any selective attrition.” pg 965.

    • 86

      de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008. “[W]e find that the measured effect of the cash treatment is larger than the effect of the in-kind treatment (a 6.7% vs. 4.2% monthly return), but the difference is not significant at conventional levels ( p = .45). Column (5) shows that we cannot rule out linearity of the returns measured by the two treatment levels. Profits increase by 760 LKR per month with the smaller treatment, 7.6% of the treatment amount, whereas they increase by 900 LKR per month, or 4.5% of the larger treatment. The difference in returns is not significant.” pg 1347.

    • 87

      de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2008. Table V.

    • 88

      de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2012. Table 3.

    • 89

      Fafchamps et al. 2011:

      • “The first four columns of Table 3 show the treatment effects for the pooled sample. All four specifications show a large positive impact of the in-kind treatment on firm profits. Monthly firm profits are estimated to be 31-43 cedis higher as a result of the 150 cedis in-kind treatment. The cash treatment is significant at the 10 percent level in the untrimmed OLS specification, but becomes insignificant when trimming or using fixed effects. The coefficients are always much smaller than for the in-kind treatment, and we can reject equality of cash and in-kind grants at the 5 percent significant level for three out of four specifications and at the 10 percent level for the other. That is, cash grants have less impact on business profits than in-kind grants.” Pg 23.
      • Study participants were selected from two cities in Ghana during an initial screen. The authors describe the rest of the selection process: “The gender and business sector of all individuals passing this screen were then recorded. This resulted in screening 7,567 households to identify 3,907 individuals who passed the screen. Only 19.4 percent of these individuals were male, confirming the predominance of women among small enterprise operations in urban Ghana. We classified business sector into male-dominated industries, identified as construction, repair services, manufacturing, and shoe making and repair; female-dominated industries, identified as hair and beauty care, and food and restaurant sales; and mixed industries, identified as trade and retail, and sewing and tailoring. This classification into male-dominated, female-dominated, or mixed was based on the gender mix of selfemployed in these industries in the 2000 Census. These industries cover the vast majority of the industries in which the self-employed work in Ghana. The 4.6 percent of those screened who worked in other industries such as communication services, pharmacy, photography, fishing, and agriculture were not included in the sample. Our aim was then to arrive at a sample of roughly 900 baseline firms stratified by gender and sector. In order to minimize the spillovers from the treatments to be carried out, we did not want to select too many individuals from any given EA who were in the same line of business. We therefore randomly selected up to 5 males in male-dominated and up to 5 males in mixed industries from each EA, and up to 3 females in female-dominated and up to 3 females in mixed industries from each EA to survey, in the process ensuring that only one individual was chosen from any given household. This resulted in an initial sample of 907 firms, consisting of 538 females and 369 males. A baseline survey of these firms was conducted in October and November 2008. The firm owners were asked for details of both their firm and their household.” Pgs 14-15.

    • 90

      McKenzie and Woodruff 2008:

      • “The results from table 5 show the treatment effects that are significant for two-stage least squares and instrumental variables random-effects estimation and marginally significant for instrumental variables fixed-effects estimation after 5 percent trimming. The estimated treatment effect ranges from 28.8 to 45.6 percent. It is well identified only for the subset of firms without very noisy profit data that take up the treatment when assigned.” Pg 473.
      • “The initial survey was conducted in November 2005, reflecting data from October 2005. Subsequent surveys were administered quarterly, with the fifth and last survey conducted in November 2006.” Pg 460.
      • “Before the first round of the survey, firms were told that the only compen- sation that they would receive for participating was a chance of receiving either cash or capital through prizes to be given after each survey round.6 The prize was a grant of 1,500 pesos (about $140). After the first round of the survey, a single draw from a computerized random number generator was used to ran- domly assign firms to treatment and control groups.7 Among the firms assigned to treatment status, the random draw also determined the round in which they would be treated and whether they would receive their grant as cash or capital for their enterprise. The results of the initial random draw were not revealed to either the survey company or the firms in the sample. After each round, the survey company was given a list of firms to which to distribute the grants. Each firm could receive a prize at most once, although this was not made explicit to the firms.” Pg 466.

    • 91

      “Estimates of the treatment effects allowing for interactions between treatment and different measures of lack of financial constraints are reported after again eliminating firms with percentage changes in profits below the 5th per- centile or above the 95th percentile. Columns 1 and 2 of table 7 show a large and strongly significant interaction effect between treatment and whether a firm owner reports that finance is not a constraint to business growth. One cannot reject the possibility that firms that report that finance is not a constraint have no increase in profits from the treatment (the point estimate actually shows a decrease in profits). The treatment effect is much stronger for the 64 percent of firms that report that finance is a constraint: monthly profits increase 1,051–1,192 pesos for these firms, a 70–79 percent return. Similar but less significant interaction effects are found for the measures of previous use of credit. One cannot reject the possibility that there is no treatment effect for firms that previously had formal loans or sup- plier credit; the treatment effect for financially constrained firms is always positive, and it is significant in all but one case (firms that have not had a formal loan).
      The different measures are combined to create a set of firms that report that finance is a constraint to business growth and that have never had a formal loan or supplier credit. The 38 percent of firms that fall into this category are referred to as “financially superconstrained.” Interacting this variable with the treatment increases the profits among these firms by 1,430–1,515 pesos—an incredible 100 percent return.” McKenzie and Woodruff 2008, Pg 479.

    • 92

      McKenzie and Woodruff 2008. “One potential concern is whether the process of trimming combined with attrition could be biasing the results. Attrition rates are similar for firms assigned to the control and treatment groups. However, after 5 percent trimming, attrition after five rounds is 58 percent for the control group and 55 percent for the group assigned to treatment.” McKenzie and Woodruff 2008 Pg 476.

    • 93
      • Pre-registration of studies is the #1 change GiveWell would like to see in the social sciences. See GiveWell's suggestions for the social sciences.
      • Pre-analysis plan To constrain our analysis, we wrote a pre-analysis plan (PAP) for this study, which is published at www.socialscienceregistry.org. Pre-analysis plans have recently gained promi- nence in economics as tools to prevent data-mining and cherry-picking of results ((Casey, Glenner- ster, and Miguel 2012); see also (Rosenthal 1979; Simes 1986; Horton and Smith 1999)). In the PAP, we specify the variables to be analyzed, the construction of indices, our approach to dealing with multiple inference, the econometric specifications to be used, and the handling of attrition. The analyses and results reported in this paper correspond to those outlined in the PAP, with the exception of the restriction of the sample to thatched-roof households at endline when identifying spillover effects to account for the time delay in applying the thatched roof criterion to the pure control group. However, this restriction is conservative.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 9.
      • Accounting for multiple comparisons Due to the large number of outcome variables in the present study, false positives are a potential concern when conventional approaches to statistical inference are used. We employ two strategies to avoid this problem, following broadly the approaches of Kling et al. (2007), Anderson (2008), and Casey et al. (2012).

        First, we compute standardized indices for several main groups of outcomes, and choose focal variables of interest for others. In particular, we use the total value of household assets, total household consumption in the past month, and total household agricultural and business income in the past month, as focal variables for the asset, consumption, and income outcome groups, respectively. For psychological well-being, food security, female empowerment, health, and education, we compute indices, which are standardized weighted averages of several key outcomes of interest within each of these groups of outcomes. The particular outcomes composing each index and the focal variables were pre-specified in our pre-analysis plan.

        Second, even after collapsing variables into indices and choosing focal variables of interest for each group of outcomes, we are still left with multiple indices, creating the need to further control the probability of Type I errors. To this end, we use the Family-Wise Error Rate (FWER; Westfall, Young, and Wright 1993; Efron and Tibshirani 1993; Anderson 2008; Casey, Glennerster, and Miguel 2012), which controls the probability of Type I errors across a group of coefficients. In our case, we control the FWER across the treatment coefficients on the indices for our main outcome groups, i.e. assets, consumption, income, psychological well-being, education, food security, health, and intrahousehold bargaining and domestic violence. As specified in our pre-analysis plan, we apply this correction to the index variables only; when discussing the results within particular outcome groups, we use conventional significance levels.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 9-10.

    • 94

      Large vs. small transfers Finally, a third treatment arm was created to study the relative impact of large compared to small transfers. To this end, 137 households in the treatment group were randomly chosen and informed in January 2012 that they would receive an additional transfer of KES 70,000 (USD 798, PPP 1,112), paid in seven monthly installments of KES 10,000 (USD 114, PPP 160) each, beginning in February 2012. Thus, the transfers previously assigned to these households, whether monthly or lump-sum, were augmented by

      KES 10,000 from February 2012 to August 20128, and therefore the total transfer amount received by these households was KES 95,200 (USD 1,085, PPP 1,525). The remaining 348 treatment households constitute the “small” transfer group, and received transfers totaling KES 25,200 (USD 287, PPP 404) per household.

      These three treatment arms were fully cross-randomized, except that, as noted above, the “large” transfers were made to existing recipients of KES 25,200 transfers in the form of a KES 70,000 top-up that was delivered as a stream of payments after respondents had already been told that they would receive KES 25,200 transfers. Section 3.1 outlines how this issue is dealt with in the analysis.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 7-8.

    • 95
      • “We conducted a randomized controlled trial (RCT) of the unconditional cash transfer program implemented by the NGO GiveDirectly in Western Kenya between 2011 and 2012, in which poor rural households received unconditional cash transfers through the mobile money system M-Pesa.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 1.
      • GiveDirectly recently expanded into Uganda. See our review of GiveDirectly.
    • 96
      • See our review of GiveDirectly for more information on GiveDirectly's standard model.
      • “[GiveDirectly] selects poor households by first identifying poor regions of Kenya according to census data. In the case of the present study, the region chosen was Rarieda, a peninsula in Lake Victoria west of Kisumu in Western Kenya. Following the choice of a region in which to operate, GD identifies target villages. In the case of Rarieda, this was achieved through a rough estimation of the population of villages and the proportion of households lacking a solid roof; villages with a high proportion of households living in thatched roof homes (rather than iron), which is GD’s targeting criterion, were prioritized. The criterion was established by GD in prior work as an objective and highly predictive indicator of poverty.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 4.

    • 97

      “This study employs a two-level cluster-randomized controlled trial. An overview of the design is shown in Figure 1. In collaboration with GD, we identified 126 villages from a list of villages in Rarieda district of Western Kenya. In the first stage of randomization, 63 of these villages were randomly chosen to be treatment villages. Within all villages, we conducted a census with the support of the village elder, which identified all eligible households within the village. As described above, eligibility was based on living in a house with a thatch roof. Control villages were only surveyed at endline; in these villages, we sampled 432 households from among eligible households, to which we refer as “pure control” households in the following.

      In treatment villages, we performed a second stage of randomization, in which we randomly assigned 50% of the eligible households in each treatment village to the treatment condition, and 50% to the control condition. This process resulted in 503 treatment households at baseline, and 505 control households in treatment villages, to which we refer as “spillover” households in the following.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 6.

    • 98

      “We therefore focus on the within-village treatment effect when reporting results; in the presence of positive spillovers, this is a conservative estimate of the treatment effect.6 Footnote 6 states:

      “Note that this strategy would overestimate the treatment effect in the presence of negative spillovers. However, we find little evidence for negative spillovers, as discussed below; this includes psychological well-being, i.e. untreated households in treatment villages did not experience a decrease in psychological well-being. We thus believe that the within-village treatment effects are a conservative estimate.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 6.

    • 99

      “Control villages were only surveyed at endline; in these villages, we sampled 432 households from among eligible households, to which we refer as “pure control” households in the following. . . . To obtain a lower-bound estimate for spillover effects, we compare households which still have thatched roofs at endline to pure control households which still have thatched roofs at endline. The logic behind this choice is the following. First, note that in the absence of spillover effects on roof purchases, this comparison provides an unbiased estimate of the spillover effects for this group of households. Second, relax the assumption of no spillovers and assume instead (as is likely) that spillover effects predominantly induce the better-off control households in treatment villages to upgrade to an iron roof. If this is the case, restricting the sample to households which still have a thatched roof at endline selects for poorer households in treatment villages, but not pure control villages, and thus provides a lower bound estimate of the spillover effect. To be conservative, in what follows we report this lower-bound estimate.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 6-7.

    • 100

      “A goal of this study was to assess the relative welfare impacts of three design features of unconditional cash transfers: the gender of the transfer recipient; the temporal structure of the transfers (monthly vs. lump-sum transfers); and the magnitude of the transfer. The intervention was therefore structured as follows:

      1. Transfers to the woman vs. the man in the household. Among households with both a primary female and primary male member, we stratified on recipient gender and randomly assigned the woman or the man to be the transfer recipient in an equal number of households. A further 110 households had a single household head and were therefore not considered in the randomization of recipient gender.

      2. Lump-sum transfers vs. monthly installments. Across all treatment households, we randomly assigned the transfer to be delivered either as a lump-sum amount, or as a series of nine monthly installments. Specifically, 244 of the 503 treatment households were assigned to the monthly condition, and 256 to the lump-sum condition. The total amount of each type of transfer was KES 25,200 (USD 287, PPP 4047). This amount includes an initial transfer of KES 1,200 (USD 14, PPP 19) to incentivize M-Pesa registration, followed by either a lump- sum payment of KES 24,000 (USD 274, PPP 384) in the lump-sum condition, or a sequence of nine monthly transfers of KES 2,800 (USD 32, PPP 45) in the monthly condition. The timing of transfers was structured as follows: in the monthly condition, recipients received the first transfer of KES 2,800 on the first of the month following M-Pesa registration, and the remaining eight transfers of KES 2,800 on the first of the eight following months. In the lump-sum condition, recipients received an initial transfer of KSH 1,200 on the first of the month following M-Pesa registration to incentivize registration, and the lump-sum transfer of KES 24,000 on the first of a month that was chosen randomly among the nine months following the time at which they were enrolled in the GD program. This procedure ensured that the monthly and lump-sum transfers had the same net present value.

      3. Large vs. small transfers. Finally, a third treatment arm was created to study the relative impact of large compared to small transfers. To this end, 137 households in the treatment group were randomly chosen and informed in January 2012 that they would receive an ad- ditional transfer of KES 70,000 (USD 798, PPP 1,112), paid in seven monthly installments of KES 10,000 (USD 114, PPP 160) each, beginning in February 2012. Thus, the transfers previously assigned to these households, whether monthly or lump-sum, were augmented by KES 10,000 from February 2012 to August 20128, and therefore the total transfer amount received by these households was KES 95,200 (USD 1,085, PPP 1,525). The remaining 348 treatment households constitute the “small” transfer group, and received transfers totaling KES 25,200 (USD 287, PPP 404) per household.

      These three treatment arms were fully cross-randomized, except that, as noted above, the “large” transfers were made to existing recipients of KES 25,200 transfers in the form of a KES 70,000 top-up that was delivered as a stream of payments after respondents had already been told that they would receive KES 25,200 transfers. Section 3.1 outlines how this issue is dealt with in the analysis.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 7-8.

    • 101

      We stress, however, that the current study was not designed to investigate long-term effects; further endline surveys will be required to obtain a more complete understanding of long term impacts." Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 15.

    • 102
      • “Endline surveys took place with September and December 31, 2012. Transfers were made between June 2011 and January 2013.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 8.
      • The minimum, mean, and maximum time between receipt of last transfer and taking the end-line survey were 1 month, 4.7 months, and 15 months. Joahnnes Haushofer, co-author of GiveDirectly RCT, email to GiveWell, November 4, 2013.

    • 103
      • “28% of the treatment group received a transfer of KES 95,200 (USD 1,085, PPP 1,525), while the remaining 72% received KES 25,200 (USD 287, PPP 404); the average transfer was thus KES 45,016 (USD 513, PPP 721).” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 12.
      • We do not know whether the marginal effects of dollars transferred increase, decrease, or stay constant as transfer size increases, but, based on our intuition and on the estimated relative effects of large transfers, we would guess that the effects of GiveDirectly’s standard transfer are substantially larger than the average treatment effects in the evaluation but are slightly less than double those effects. Recipients of large transfers increased their assets by $253 more than recipients of small transfers. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 29. Point estimates suggested that recipients of large transfers increased their consumption by $20/month more than recipients of small transfers but this estimate was not statistically significant. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 29. The average treatment effect was a $279 increase in assets and a $36/month increase in consumption. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 29. The effect of increasing the transfer size by about $800 from a small transfer to a large transfer was therefore positive but smaller than the overall treatment effect for grants averaging $513. This may be evidence in favor of diminishing returns but may also be evidence that recipients of large transfers spend their transfers more slowly.

    • 104

      The PPP adjusted values of the small, mean, and large transfer are $404, $721, and $1,525 respectively. “28% of the treatment group received a transfer of KES 95,200 (USD 1,085, PPP 1,525), while the remaining 72% received KES 25,200 (USD 287, PPP 404); the average transfer was thus KES 45,016 (USD 513, PPP 721).” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 12.

    • 105

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 29.

    • 106

      Non-land assets includes “the value, in USD PPP, of all moveable assets the household owns, including savings, plus the value of the roof of the home.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 10.

    • 107

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 30.

    • 108

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 30.

    • 109

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 30.

    • 110

      “Cash transfers increase the likelihood of having an iron roof by 23 percentage points relative to a control group mean of 16%.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 16.

    • 111

      “Recipients of large transfers are 23 percentage points more likely to have an iron roof than recipients of small transfers.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 17.

    • 112
      • “The purchase of an iron roof represents an expenditure of approximately KES 35,220 (USD 402, PPP 564), or 75% of the average transfer value. In addition to a store of value (roofs can be resold), an iron roof potentially provides an investment return to households by obviating the need to periodically replace their thatched roofs, which must be done ever 1 to 2 years, costing approximately KES 4,800 (USD 55, PPP 77) per replacement, implying a simple return on the investment in the roof of between 7 and 14%. Reported savings balances double as a result of cash transfers, but from low initial levels (PPP USD 10).” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 16-17.
      • We have not vetted the methodology used to estimate the return on investment for iron roofs. See Data on roofs for more information.

    • 113

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 33.

    • 114

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 33.

    • 115

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 31.

    • 116

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 31.

    • 117

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 35.

    • 118

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 35.

    • 119

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 29.

    • 120

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 29.

    • 121

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 31.

    • 122

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 31.

    • 123

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 31.

    • 124

      “Food security is low in this population. Though instance of skipped meals are not extreme, 20% of the control group reports that not all household members usually eat until they are content, 23% of respondents report sleeping hungry in the last week, and only 36% report having enough food in the house for the next day.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 18.

    • 125
      • ”With one exception (where the coefficient is small and non-significant), all of the signs of the coefficients are in the direction of increased food security, resulting in a statistically significant 0.25 SD increase in our food security index. This effect is driven by a broad range of individual variables, many of which are individually highly significant. For instance, cash transfers reduce the likelihood of the respondent having gone to bed hungry in the preceding week from 23% to 16% (a 30% decrease), increase the likelihood of having enough food in the house for the next day from 36% to 43% (a 20% increase), and reduce by 42% the number of days children go without food.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 18.
      • This effect was driven by an improvement in a broad range of food-security related variables such as a reduction in “the likelihood of the respondent having gone to bed hungry in the preceding week from 23% to 16% . . . [an] increase [in] the likelihood of having enough food in the house for the next day from 36% to 43% . . . and [a reduction] by 42% [in] the number of days children go without food.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 18.

    • 126
      • The point estimate suggests that recipients of large transfers reported 0.16 standard deviations higher on the food security index than recipients of small transfers, but this estimate was statistically insignificant and imprecise. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 29.
      • ”The test of joint significance, however, rejects equality among large and small transfer recipients in terms of food security.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 18.

    • 127
      • “As discussed above, we fail to detect an impact of cash transfers on our index of health outcomes.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 19.
      • “Consistent with the lack of an average impact on our educational index, in Table 7 we do not detect significant impacts on educational outcomes.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 19.

    • 128
      • ”These effects translate into an overall increase in monthly revenues for recipient households, PPP USD 15 higher (including revenues from the sale of animals and meat), but we do not observe a significant increase in estimated profits from self-employment.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 19.
      • According to Table 5, total revenue was about $17 per month higher for treatment than for control groups. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, Table 5.
      • In particular, the RCT found no increase in imputed or self-reported non-agricultural profits. There was a $1.21 per month decrease in farm profits and a $1.68 per month increase in livestock flow profits. Total profits were estimated to decrease by a statistically insignificant $0.16 per month (with a standard error of $3.74). Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 33.

    • 129

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 33.

    • 130

      “Treatment effects on psychological and neurobiological outcomes are shown in Table 8. Overall, we find a 0.20 SD increase in the index of psychological well-being in the treatment compared to the spillover group.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 19.

    • 131

    • 132

      “The overall index is 0.35 SD higher for households receiving a large transfer compared to those receiving a small transfer . . . .” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 20.

    • 133

      “As discussed above, we observe a statistically significant spillover effect on the female empowerment index: the index is 0.23 SD higher for control house- holds in treatment villages than for pure control households.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 21.

    • 134

      “As changes in domestic violence were hypothesized to arise through mechanisms directly associated with cash transfers (such as a change in women’s bargaining power, or a reduction in domestic tension over economic hardships), these spillover effects are somewhat surprising. One possible explanation is that the results are simply an artifact of reporting bias, where the spillover sample believed that a different answer was desired from them than the control group. However, given that we do not find spillover effects in other measures that target unobservable outcomes, we find this explanation implausible. Another possibility is that the presence of the cash transfer program in the village motivated the husbands in untreated households to change their behavior in the hope of receiving transfers in the future. For instance, knowing that the primary female in the household was equally likely to receive the transfer as the primary male, men may have shifted their behavior to establish better relationships with their spouse. Alternatively, the spillover effect may operate through changes in attitudes among either or both husbands and wives in non-treated households. Our data does not distinguish between these possibilities; we find these unexpected results intriguing and believe they warrant further investigation.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 21.

    • 135

      “Column (3) in Table 1 reports the coefficients on the spillover dummies. These are generally small and not significant, with one notable exception: we observe an increase of 0.23 SD in the female empowerment index among the control group in treatment villages, significant at the 5% level using conventional p-values and at the 10% level using FWER-corrected p-values.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 12.

    • 136

      Point estimates suggest that the program reduced the value of nonrecipients’ non-land assets by about $19, reduced their consumption by $8 per month, and reduced their total revenues by $5 per month, but these estimates are not statistically significant. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 29.

    • 137
      • ”There are no significant village-level effects on any variable group, suggesting that cash transfers to a group of particularly disadvantaged households within these villages did not impact the general village-level economy.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 22.
      • Standard errors on these estimates appear relatively large. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 38. However, the study does not include a complete description of how these indices were constructed so we are unsure of whether these estimates include the possibility of meaningful village-level economic effects.

    • 138

      “Column (4) in Table 1 reports the coefficients and standard errors comparing female to male re- cipient households on the index variables. With the exception of psychological well-being, which is significant at the 10% level, none of the differences between the treatment effects for transfers to the female vs. the male are statistically significant at conventional significance levels. Thus we find little evidence that providing cash transfers to women vs. men differentially affect outcomes. However, we note a trend in the point estimates suggesting that transferring cash to the primary male in the household leads to a larger impact on standard measures of economic welfare, namely assets and consumption, while transferring cash to the primary female in the household improves outcomes most likely to benefit children, i.e. food security, health, and education, as well as psychological well-being and female empowerment. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 13.

    • 139

      “Results are shown in column (5) of Table 1. The joint significance across outcomes is at p 0.05, suggesting that monthly and lump-sum transfers have significantly different effects on our outcomes. In the individual variables, we find that monthly payments increase food security by 0.26 SD relative to lump-sum payments, which is statistically different from zero, and some indication that lump sum transfers lead to higher asset values.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 14.

    • 140

      Large vs. small transfers Finally, a third treatment arm was created to study the relative impact of large compared to small transfers. To this end, 137 households in the treatment group were randomly chosen and informed in January 2012 that they would receive an additional transfer of KES 70,000 (USD 798, PPP 1,112), paid in seven monthly installments of KES 10,000 (USD 114, PPP 160) each, beginning in February 2012. Thus, the transfers previously assigned to these households, whether monthly or lump-sum, were augmented by

      KES 10,000 from February 2012 to August 20128, and therefore the total transfer amount received by these households was KES 95,200 (USD 1,085, PPP 1,525). The remaining 348 treatment households constitute the “small” transfer group, and received transfers totaling KES 25,200 (USD 287, PPP 404) per household.

      These three treatment arms were fully cross-randomized, except that, as noted above, the “large” transfers were made to existing recipients of KES 25,200 transfers in the form of a KES 70,000 top-up that was delivered as a stream of payments after respondents had already been told that they would receive KES 25,200 transfers. Section 3.1 outlines how this issue is dealt with in the analysis.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 7-8.

    • 141

      “We find large and highly significant differences between large and small transfers, all in the direction of “better” outcomes for large transfers. The joint significance across outcome has a p-value of less than 0.001. Regarding individual outcomes, most prominently, the increase in asset holdings resulting from the large transfer is approximately twice as large as that for the small transfer. The differences between the subgroups on these outcomes are statistically significant in terms of both conventional and FWER-adjusted p-values. In addition, we find that larger transfers improve the psychological well-being of household members to a greater extent than small transfers; this difference is also significant in terms of both standard and FWER-adjusted p-values. Finally, we observe an additional increase in female empowerment for large transfers, significant at the 5% level using conventional p-values, but not FWER-corrected inference.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 14.

    • 142

      Among households receiving small transfers, some households received their last transfer less than a month before the end-line survey while others received their final transfers more than four months before being surveyed. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013 use this variation to attempt to determine whether effects of transfers fade out immediately after the transfers end. They find:

      • moderate evidence suggesting that the impact on asset values was maintained more than four months after the final transfer;
      • moderate evidence suggesting that the impact on consumption may have declined for households receiving monthly installments but not for households that received lump-sum transfers (which spent less on consumption in the first place);
      • no evidence of changing impacts on revenues over time;
      • moderate evidence suggesting that the impact on food security for households receiving monthly installments declines over time (but remains distinguishable from zero).

      “The figure indicates that the observed average impact on overall asset values in treatment households persists over time: both for households receiving lump-sum and monthly transfers, levels of asset holdings are significantly higher than in the control group at all time horizons. We observe no decrease over time in either group; the 95% confidence intervals of the coefficients overlap across all time horizons.

      Similarly, consumption is elevated relative to control at all time horizons. The point estimates suggest declining impacts on total non-durable consumption over time for the group receiving monthly transfers, though not for the lump sum group; however, the confidence intervals of the treatment effects at shorter vs. longer time horizons overlap, i.e. these differences are not statistically significant.

      For agricultural and business revenue, we find no strong indication of changing impacts over time; however, note that the treatment effects are small overall and not distinguishable from zero in this restricted and highly disaggregated sample.

      Cash transfers also had persistent impacts on food security. However, this effect is driven by the monthly transfer group; in the lump-sum group we find little evidence of treatment effects at any time horizon, consistent with the larger overall treatment effect on food security in the monthly group. We also observe that the impact on food security is largest among the group receiving contemporaneous transfers; the treatment effect on food security falls by more than 50% over time in the group receiving monthly transfers, although remains positive and statistically different from zero.

      The temporal dynamics of cash transfers for additional outcomes (psychological well being, health, education, female empowerment) reveal no differential impacts at different delays. In the case of psychological well-being, this reflects the fact that the restricted sample used here is underpowered to detect the overall treatment effect we observe for this outcome measure.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, p. 16. This analysis has extremely low power and includes only households receiving small transfers, so we do not have high confidence in the results.

    • 143

      “Lump-sum transfers vs. monthly installments. Across all treatment households, we randomly assigned the transfer to be delivered either as a lump-sum amount, or as a series of nine monthly installments. Specifically, 244 of the 503 treatment households were assigned to the monthly condition, and 256 to the lump-sum condition. The total amount of each type of transfer was KES 25,200 (USD 287, PPP 4047). This amount includes an initial transfer of KES 1,200 (USD 14, PPP 19) to incentivize M-Pesa registration, followed by either a lump- sum payment of KES 24,000 (USD 274, PPP 384) in the lump-sum condition, or a sequence of nine monthly transfers of KES 2,800 (USD 32, PPP 45) in the monthly condition. The timing of transfers was structured as follows: in the monthly condition, recipients received the first transfer of KES 2,800 on the first of the month following M-Pesa registration, and the remaining eight transfers of KES 2,800 on the first of the eight following months. In the lump-sum condition, recipients received an initial transfer of KSH 1,200 on the first of the month following M-Pesa registration to incentivize registration, and the lump-sum transfer of KES 24,000 on the first of a month that was chosen randomly among the nine months following the time at which they were enrolled in the GD program. This procedure ensured that the monthly and lump-sum transfers had the same net present value.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, p. 7. Households that received lump sums in early months therefore received their final transfers much earlier than other households.

    • 144
      • For example, the survey’s questions about non-agriculture flow expenses, non-agricultural business investment in durables, farm revenue, and farm flow expenses are backwards looking and are therefore cover periods of time when more households had not received their full transfers.
      • ”In the last 12 months what was spent on machinery or durable goods (e.g., tools, cooking pots, overs, sewing machines)?” GiveDirectly Survey for Randomized Controlled Trial.
      • ”In the last 3 months what was spent for this enterprise on:
        • Electricity
        • Salaries/wages
        • Water
        • Transport
        • Purchase of inputs, inventory, and products
        • Other costs (exclude machinery, tools, durables already mentioned in V84)”

        GiveDirectly Survey for Randomized Controlled Trial.

      • ”[During the long/short rain season] How much did your household receive for the amount it sold?”
      • ”In the last long[/short] rains season how much did your household pay for:
        • Seeds
        • Fertilizers/pesticides/herbicides
        • Hiring Machines (e.g. for plowing or spraying)
        • Water (including irrigation water)
        • Hiring Labor
        • Other expenses

        GiveDirectly Survey for Randomized Controlled Trial.

    • 145

      “In addition to a store of value (roofs can be resold), an iron roof potentially provides an investment return to households by obviating the need to periodically replace their thatched roofs, which must be done every 1 to 2 years, costing approximately KES 4,800 (USD 55, PPP 77) per replacement, implying a simple return on the investment in the roof of between 7 and 14%.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 16-17.

    • 146

      On average, treatment led to a $279 increase in non-land assets and a 23 percentage point increase in the likelihood of having a non-thatched roof. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 30. The study estimates that iron roofs are worth “PPP 564.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 16. Iron roof purchases therefore might account for as much as 0.23*564/279 = 47% of the increase in assets.

    • 147
      • Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, p. 25.
      • ”A goal of this study was to assess the relative welfare impacts of three design features of unconditional cash transfers: the gender of the transfer recipient; the temporal structure of the transfers (monthly vs. lump-sum transfers); and the magnitude of the transfer.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, p. 7.

    • 148

      “We therefore focus on the within-village treatment effect when reporting results; in the presence of positive spillovers, this is a conservative estimate of the treatment effect.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, p. 6.

    • 149

      “We therefore focus on the within-village treatment effect when reporting results; in the presence of positive spillovers, this is a conservative estimate of the treatment effect.6” Footnote six says: “Note that this strategy would overestimate the treatment effect in the presence of negative spillovers. However, we find little evidence for negative spillovers, as discussed below; this includes psychological well-being, i.e. untreated households in treatment villages did not experience a decrease in psychological well-being. We thus believe that the within-village treatment effects are a conservative estimate.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, p. 6.

    • 150
      • “Recipients increased asset holdings by PPP USD 279.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 2.
      • ”Similarly, the transfers increase the treatment group’s average monthly consumption by PPP USD 36 at endline, which corresponds to 23% of average consumption among control households.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 12.

    • 151
      • “In addition to a store of value (roofs can be resold), an iron roof potentially provides an investment return to households by obviating the need to periodically replace their thatched roofs, which must be done ever 1 to 2 years, costing approximately KES 4,800 (USD 55, PPP 77) per replacement, implying a simple return on the investment in the roof of between 7 and 14%.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 16-17.
      • We have not vetted the methodology used to estimate the return on investment for iron roofs. See Data on roofs for more information.

    • 152

      "Cash transfers increase the likelihood of having an iron roof by 23 percentage points relative to a control group mean of 16%. . . . Recipients of large transfers are 23 percentage points more likely to have an iron roof than recipients of small transfers.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pgs. 17.

    • 153

      “Recipient households also report PPP USD 2 higher income from the sale of livestock and meat than control households. These effects translate into an overall increase in monthly revenues for recipient households, PPP USD 15 higher (including revenues from the sale of animals and meat), but we do not observe a significant increase in estimated profits from self-employment.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, p. 6.

    • 154

      “YOP invited groups of young adults, aged roughly 16 to 35, to apply for cash grants in order to start a skilled trade such as carpentry or tailoring. . . . Groups in our sample ranged from 10 to 40 people, averaging 22, mostly from the same village. Half the groups existed already, often for several years, as farm cooperatives, or sports, drama, or microfinance clubs. New groups formed specifically for YOP were often initiated by a respected community member (e.g. teachers, local leaders, or existing tradespersons) and sought members through social networks. In our sample, 5% of groups are all female and 12% are all male, but most groups are mixed—about one-third female on average.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pgs. 6-7.

    • 155

      “From Table II, we see that members of the 535 eligible groups were generally young, rural, poor, credit constrained, and underemployed. In 2008 they were 25 years on average, mainly aged 16 to 35. Less than a quarter lived in a town, and most lived in villages of 100 to 2000 households. A quarter did not finish primary school, but on average they reached eighth grade.

      In 2008 the sample report 11 hours of work a week. Half these hours are a mix of low-skill labor or petty business, while the other half is in agriculture—a mix of subsistence and rudimentary cash crop production on small rain-fed plots with little equipment or inputs. Almost half of our sample reports no employment in the past month, and only 6% are engaged in a skilled trade. Cash earnings in the past month average roughly a dollar a day. Savings are roughly $15 on average. Only 11% report any savings, and these report $58 at the median. 33% hold loans, but these are small: under $7 at the median among those who have any loans, mainly from friends and family. About 10% report they could obtain a large loan of 1,000,000 UGX (about $580). Although poor by any measure, these applicants are slightly wealthier and more educated than their peers. If we compare our sample to people of the same gender, age and district in a 2008 population-based household survey by the government, our sample has 1.7 years more education, 0.15 SD more wealth, is 7.5 pp more urban and 5.4 pp more likely to be married, and has 1.6 fewer household members (See Appendix B.3). Given that the three most war-affected districts did not participate in the YOP evaluation, and only 3% were involved in an armed group in any fashion.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 11.

    • 156
      • Facilitators helped the groups prepare the proposals. ”Many applicants were functionally illiterate and so YOP also required “facilitators”—usually a local government employee, teacher, or community leader—to meet with the group several times, advise them on program rules, and help prepare the written proposals. Groups chose their own facilitators, and facilitators received 2% of funded proposals (up to $200).” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 7.
      • “Second, groups had to submit a written proposal stating how they would use the grant for non-agricultural skills training and enterprise start-up costs. They could request up to $10,000.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 7.

    • 157

      “Finally, successful proposals received a large lump sum cash transfer to a bank account in the names of the management committee, with no government monitoring thereafter.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 8.

    • 158

      “Per capita grant size varied across groups due to variation in group size and amounts requested. 80% of grants were between $200 and $600 per capita, averaging $382.“ Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 8.

    • 159

      “Most groups proposed a single trade for all, but a third of groups proposed that different members would train two to three different trades. Females and mixed groups often chose trades common to both genders, such as tailoring or hairstyling. Males and a small number of females often chose trades such as carpentry or welding.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 7.

    • 160
      • “At the median, they estimate they spent 11% on skills training, 52% on tools, 13% on materials, and 24% was shared in cash or spent on other things.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 17.
      • Training generally consisted of apprenticeships with artisans or small institutes. “In preparing the proposal, groups selected their own trainers, typically a local artisan or small institute. These are commonplace in Uganda (as in much of Africa) and there is a tradition of artisans taking on paying students as apprentices. Most of these artisans and institutes had been in existence more than five years, and most took students previously. In our sample, few were located in the village but the median artisan or institute was within 8km. Groups would travel to be closer to trainers, or paid transport and upkeep for trainers to come to them. Thus groups were seldom constrained in their choice of vocation by local trainers. This group-based training generally produced bulk discounts, and enabled a wider choice of vocations.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 7.

    • 161
      • “Between 2008 and 2010, 68% percent of the treatment group enrolled in vocational training, compared to 15% of the control group.14 On average, treatment translates into 340 more hours of vocational training than controls.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 17-18.
      • “Among those who enroll in any training, 38% train in tailoring, 23% in carpentry, 13% in metalwork, 8% in hairstyling, and the remainder in miscellaneous other trades.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 18.

    • 162

      “Treatment also increases capital stocks. We calculate the respondent’s estimated total value of all business assets and deflate it to 2008 UGX. From Table III, the control group reports UGX 290,200 ($167) of business assets in 2010 and 392,800 ($228) in 2012. By 2010 treatment increases capital stocks by UGX 377,023 ($219), a 131% increase over the control group, and by 2012 stocks increase by UGX 224,986 ($130), a 57% increase over the control group. The relative impact falls over time as the control group’s investment begins to catch up, rising 38% between 2010 and 2012 (Table IV). The bulk of this investment is in petty business and agriculture.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 18.

    • 163

      “The program increases total hours worked per week by 4.1 in 2010 and 5.5 in 2012—a 17% increase in labor supply relative to controls both years.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 20.

    • 164

      “This increase is almost entirely in skilled trades. Treatment also results in a very small but statistically significant increase in high-skill wage labor, which includes teaching, health work, government jobs, or other semi-skilled wage work. As a consequence, by 2010, 44% of the treatment group report at least one hour worked in a skilled trade, rising to 48% by 2012. Thus participation and hours in a skilled trade are 2 to 2.5 times greater than in the control group.

      The treatment group does not decrease their hours in other activities, however. Agricultural hours rise at the same rate in the treatment and control groups. Moreover, even in 2012, the treatment group still works twice as many hours in agriculture hours as skilled work. Trades remain a supplement to income, and young adults are primarily engaged in agriculture. Only 7% of the treatment group report 30 or more hours a week in a trade, 4 pp more than the control group. Most are simply adding this new high-skill trade to their portfolio of work activities.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 20.

    • 165
      • ”Assignment to receive a YOP grant increases earnings by UGX 14,605 ($8.50) in 2010 and UGX 18,186 ($10.50) in 2012—increases of 41% and 38% relative to controls (Table III).” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 22.
      • Even though the absolute difference between treatment and control group earnings increased from 2010 to 2012, the difference slightly decreased in percentage terms. This is because average control group earnings increased by 40% over the two year period. “The control group reports monthly cash earnings of approximately UGX 30,825 ($18) in 2008, UGX 35,200 ($20) in 2010 and UGX 47,800 ($28) in 2012.19 Such growth may come in part from a growing economy, but also arises from young people who are gradually increasing their capital stocks and output over time by investing earnings.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 22.

    • 166
      • “We estimate these earnings impacts represent an average annual return on investment (ROI) of 30 to 50%. The 2010 and 2012 earnings ITT estimates in Table III represent ROIs of 30% and 39% on the per capita grant.21 The 2010 and 2012 TOT estimates represent ROIs of 36% and 49%. If we adjust earnings to remove “wages” for additional labor supplied, the treatment effects and ROIs are equal or greater.22 All these ROIs are large relative to the real commercial lending rates of 10 to 30% common among medium-size firms in Uganda. They also approach the ROIs estimated from cash grants to existing microenterprises in Sri Lanka, Mexico, and Ghana (de Mel et al., 2008; McKenzie and Woodruff, 2008; Udry and Anagol, 2006).” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 24.
      • This estimate of the program’s ROI assumes that the cost of the grant was the only cost of the program. We do not know anything about the administrative costs of the program, including facilitating applications, but would guess that they are low relative to the cost of the grant.
      • The ROI estimate is meant to be a measure of the grant’s permanent effect on income. We would guess that earnings gains that have been maintained four years after the grant was distributed will be maintained indefinitely. However, there is evidence that some treatment group members divested from the grant, which could lead income gains to dissipate over time. See later in this page for more discussion of divestment.

    • 167

      “Assignment to receive a YOP grant increases earnings by UGX 14,605 ($8.50) in 2010 and UGX 18,186 ($10.50) in 2012—increases of 41% and 38% relative to controls (Table III). We cannot reject the hypothesis that the earnings treatment effect is equal at both endlines. If we divide earnings by hours worked to calculate an average “wage”, we see it is very low—UGX 500 to 850, or $0.29 to 0.49—and it does not increase significantly as a result of treatment (Table III). This implies that earnings gains come from increasing inputs, not productivity.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pgs. 22-23.

    • 168
      • The measure of durable assets is “a z-score constructed by taking the first principal component of 70 measures of land, housing quality, and household assets.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 22.
      • ”The control group’s durable assets rise by 0.1 SD from 2008 to 2010, and rise by 0.21 SD from 2010 to 2012 (Tables II and III). The indices use the same assets and weights at each survey for comparability. The program impacts are of similar magnitudes: durable assets are 0.10 SD greater than the control group in 2010 and 0.18 SD greater in 2012.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 23.
      • The measure of non-durable consumption is “a z-score constructed by taking the first principal component of 30 select food items consumed in the past three days and expenditures on 28 select non-food items.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 22.
      • ”The impact of the program on non-durable consumption in 2012 is identical, 0.18 SD.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 23.
      • Finally, at both endlines the program increases subjective well-being by 12 to 13% relative to controls. Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 23.
      • For difference in mean subjective well being scores, see Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013 Table III. Treatment improved subjective well-being by 0.4 points on a scale from 1 to 9.

    • 169
      • ”Our measures are based mainly on existing measures and include indices of: (1) kin integration, capturing four measures of household relations; (2) community participation, capturing ten measures of associational life and collective action; (3) community public good contributions (2012 only) including seven types of goods; (4) anti-social behavior, based on eight forms of aggressive behavior with neighbors, community leaders, and police, plus 18 additional measures in 2012; and (5) protest attitudes and participation, based on 7 measures of participation in and attitudes around violent anti-government protests following the 2011 elections.
        Overall, we see little evidence of a positive social impact on males after two years, and none whatsoever after four years. Table VIII reports impacts on the main outcome families (disaggregated summary statistics and treatments effects are reported in Appendix B.9). The point estimates are typically less than 0.1 or 0.05 SD, and standard errors on these z-scores are equally small, suggesting we can rule out medium to large changes. Just two of the 27 regressions show a small, statistically significant impact, and both at the 2-year endline. We regard these as at best temporary effects and probably statistical anomalies.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pgs. 26-27.
      • ”Admittedly, our data have limitations: they are self-reported, and there were no major episodes of unrest to measure. We also did not measure every possible externality, especially collective or general equilibrium changes that accompany broader structural change. Nonetheless, the absence of a large change on the individual margin runs counter to many expectations.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 27.

    • 170

      “A third limitation is that we are unable to evaluate the non-cash components of YOP. We speculate that the group and business plan may have been important as initial commitment devices, though the sustained investment and earnings growth we see over four years suggests that such restrictions were not vital to long-term success. Alternatively, these restrictions may have helped screen out applicants uninterested in becoming artisanal entrepreneurs.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 27.

    • 171

      The government invited young adults to form village groups and prepare a proposal for how they would use a grant to train in and start an independent trade. Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 1.

    • 172

      ”In the end, YOP appears to have reached a group of motivated, able young people, who on average were neither exceptionally poor nor uneducated relative to their peers, in an economy with little financial depth but bouncing back from civil strife. Our conceptual framework suggests this is exactly the group to benefit from a windfall. This was not entirely accidental—the requirements to form groups, prepare proposals, and wait a long period of time before any grant, with a low probability of success, were designed in part to allow patient, able people with an affinity for vocations to signal their “type”. This may have been the most important function of the groups and proposal in terms of ensuring that the grants were channeled into new employment.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 27.

    • 173

      “We speculate that the group and business plan may have been important as initial commitment devices, though the sustained investment and earnings growth we see over four years suggests that such restrictions were not vital to long-term success.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 2.

    • 174

      “Per capita grant size varied across groups due to variation in group size and amounts requested. 80% of grants were between $200 and $600 per capita, averaging $382.“ Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 8.

    • 175
      • ”Table IV also reports changes in capital stock levels over time. From 2010 to 2012 the treatment group’s capital stock falls 19%, overall and with both genders. This decline is not statistically significant, however.

        Nonetheless, some in the treatment group do divest substantially. 89% of the treatment groups received a grant but only 68% of treatment group members report enrolling in training and, from Table III, only 48% of the treatment group worked any hours in a skilled trade in the month before the 2012 survey. Thus nearly half of the treated (and a third of those who trained in a trade) are not practicing a trade four years later. Table IV reports changes in capital stock over time in four endogenous subgroups. First, the 11% of the treatment sample who did not receive a grant look much like the control group in that capital stocks rise steeply over time as they accumulate through retained earnings. Second, the 21% who were funded but did not train have capital stocks close to the level of the control group in 2010 and 2012, suggesting that they did not participate meaningfully in the group grant. Their capital stocks rise over time, perhaps due to accumulation of retained earnings. Third, the 48% who were funded, trained, and still practice the trade in 2012 have capital stocks that hold basically steady, declining only 7%. Finally, the 20% who were funded and trained but did not practice a trade in the month before the 2012 survey see their capital stocks decline precipitously back to the level of the control group. These may be the “low ability” or impatient types in our conceptual framework, who find it optimal to divest. We consider alternative explanations in Section 7.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 19.

      • ”Several patterns suggest that the sample should see substantial growth over time: the regional economy is growing; earnings growth barely slows between the first and second endlines, and the average treatment person is still not fully employed after four years. We do not, however, see sustained growth in capital stocks in the treatment group, even though the treatment group enjoyed robust and rising earnings that could be used to expand the enterprise.

        Does failure to do so mean that the treatment group may have reached their steady state level of capital, and will taper in their growth in the future? It is possible the program brought the average person to their efficient scale given their current entrepreneurial abilities. Half of the treated do not divest, but neither do they grow their capital stock. The treatment group may have yet to take full advantage of their initial capital investments, even after four years. The increase in the earnings treatment effect between the two endlines while labor and capital inputs stay roughly constant is consistent with this interpretation. Only future follow-up of the sample will tell.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pgs. 31-32.

    • 176

      “In 2008 they were 25 years on average, mainly aged 16 to 35.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 11.

    • 177

      “We have comparable population data on age, gender, urban status, marital status, schooling, household size, durable assets, main occupation, and district. We can estimate the PATE by reweighting our sample to reflect the distribution of these characteristics. Since 85% of our sample is aged 18 to 30, we first calculate a PATE for this age range alone, mainly adjusting for the fact that the general population is somewhat poorer and less educated. Investment and earnings treatment effects among 18 to 30 year olds are broadly similar in the population and the sample, though the PATE is marginally (but not statistically significantly) lower. If we consider the full age range, the PATE primarily reweights the treatment effects to older persons. Employment impacts are comparable and the estimated effect on durable assets increases, but the business asset and earnings PATEs are much smaller, and not statistically significant. Full results are in Appendix B.3. We treat these results with caution, however, since young adults are selected into our sample because of unobserved initiative, connections or affinity for entrepreneurship. Thus the PATE probably overstates the true population average treatment effect.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pgs. 24-25.

    • 178

      “The empirical strategy for the evaluation consisted of a randomized experimental design and mixed methods data collection. Following the baseline survey with all 1,800 beneficiaries in mid-2009, IPA held public lotteries in Gulu and Kitgum to randomly assign the 120 program villages to Phase 1 or Phase 2 (stratified by district). In this wait-list control design, all beneficiaries were guaranteed to receive the program, but not all at once. By serving 900 beneficiaries per phase, AVSI had to scale-up their program by 300 percent. Therefore, it was not possible to serve all intended beneficiaries at once.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 5.

    • 179
      • Business skills training. “AVSI provides a brief course in basic business skills for all participants. This course typically runs for five days and covers topics necessary for the planning, starting, and managing of simple business activities. The curriculum has been adapted for illiterate users and AVSI staff is experienced in effectively working with illiterate beneficiaries, who are the majority of the target group of this proposed program. Trainers are AVSI staff members with years of experience in the psychosocial and livelihoods sector and with specific training in business skills, group dynamics and problem solving within the world of business.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 3.
      • Business plans and grants. ”Clients submit business plans to the AVSI team after the training. Each plan is reviewed and discussed with the client. Upon approval, the client is eligible for a start-up grant. . . .

        All clients receive a start-up grant of approximately $150 USD to be used for the implementation of approved business plans. In the past, this money has been disbursed all at once and in several tranches.” Blattman et al 2013, pgs. 3-4.

      • Follow-up. “AVSI understands that the importance of follow-up visits to the individual and the groups is important from two sides: the inter-personal and the business dimension. Many years of experience have demonstrated to AVSI that on-going support for young, new entrepreneurs is essential to help them succeed and address the challenges that arise with every nascent business endeavor. Clients receive at least three follow up visits.

        On the business side, AVSI staff maintains close supervision of business activities for the first few business cycles, providing advice on meeting market challenges and implementing sound business practices. AVSI staff have been trained in business skills and most importantly have years of experience within the environment of small enterprises in the specific geographic districts of this program, with accumulated links to successful businesses and an array of formal and informal financial services.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 4.

    • 180

      ”Support for Business Networks. AVSI’s experience with this program model suggested that the target women lack support networks that they could use for business advice, savings and lending, and other support. Development programs commonly form villagers, especially women, into groups for this purpose. It is universal, yet untested. We wanted to test whether this was an effective way to increase success and well-being. Therefore in the 60 Phase 1 villages we instituted a cross-cutting design (CCD), where women in 30 of the Phase 1 villages were encouraged to form a mutual support group, elect a leadership, and hold regular meetings. The groups received two days of advising and team building exercises. When we conduct the interim survey at the end of Phase 1, we will be able to measure the impact of these women’s support networks on all of our outcomes of interest.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 5.

    • 181

      “Phase 1 started in mid 2009 and Phase 2 began in early 2011 following the endline survey of all 1,800 beneficiaries in November 2010. By comparing the beneficiaries in Phase 1 to those in Phase 2, who had not received the program at the time of the endline survey, we were able to estimate the medium-run impacts of the program on our core outcomes of interest: sustained livelihoods, poverty, empowerment, gender-based violence, family education and health, and psychosocial well being.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 5.

    • 182

      “Phase 1 started in mid 2009 and Phase 2 began in early 2011 following the endline survey of all 1,800 beneficiaries in November 2010.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 5.

    • 183

      One-third received 2 visits and one-third received five visits. “To the best of our knowledge, the economic and social impacts of follow-up support to recipients of economic assistance programs like WINGS has not been rigorously evaluated. The most relevant literature may be the role and impact of loan officers in microfinance programs, but the evidence base is very limited (Siwale & Ritchie, 2011). Given the logistical challenges and high cost of facilitating multiple home visits and monitoring, it is important to demonstrate the cost-effectiveness of this component of the program. In the second phase of the study, beneficiaries were randomized to receive 0 follow-up visits, 2 visits, or 5 visits to estimate the effect of follow-up ‘dose’. In addition to studying the impact of dose, we also attempted to tease apart the mechanism of follow-up impact—‘accountability’ versus longer-term advising and relationship building—by examining differences in early spending decisions based on beneficiaries’ expectations of follow-up.” Blattman et al 2013, pgs. 5-6.

    • 184

      “At the start of the program, AVSI worked with leaders in 120 communities in Gulu and Kitgum districts to identify and screen 2,300 potential beneficiaries. Following this initial assessment, AVSI selected 1,800 of the most vulnerable residents between the ages of 14 and 30 (86% female), approximately 15 per program community. “ Blattman et al 2013, pgs. 3-4.

    • 185

      Blattman et al 2013, pg. 9.

    • 186

      “Business plans proposed by WINGS recipients were then received and approved by AVSI. Figure 5, taken from an AVSI presentation, shows the breakdown of these approved businesses by type. Over half the businesses centered on the general selling of mixed items, with the rest being dominated by selling of livestock, fish and farm products.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 12.

    • 187

      Blattman et al 2013, pg. 12.

    • 188
      • “We presented clients with a pile of stones and a sheet with pictures of twelve kinds of expenditures (which we classify later on into these four categories). Clients were asked to allocate the stones according to how they spent the grant, and the proportions are calculated from the relative balance of stone.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 38.
      • Blattman et al 2013, pg. 38.

    • 189
      • “Both treatment and control groups report about 36,000 UGX (USD 14.49) in spending. . . . The results differ in the level—if the clients had spent a quarter to a third of the grant on business, we would expect 90,000 to 120,000 UGX in spending (USD 36.15 – 48.20).” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 39.
      • According to this survey, about 44% of business expenditures were spent on raw materials and 24% were spent on dues, fees, and other general expenditures. The rest was spent on purchasing inventory, tools or equipment, structural improvement, or materials. Blattman et al 2013, pg. 39.

    • 190

      Blattman et al 2013, pg. 16, Figure 9.

    • 191
      • The full WINGS program (including follow-up) increased beneficiaries’ monthly net earnings by an average of $6.50. “For the average WINGS beneficiary, net cash earnings increased UGX 16,211 in the month before the survey, a 98% increase over controls. . . . In absolute terms, an increase of UGX 16,211 does not seem large (about $6.50 at market exchange rates of 2500). . . . In absolute terms, an increase of UGX 16,211 does not seem large (about $6.50 at market exchange rates of 2500).” Blattman et al 2013, pgs. 14-15.
      • Using data from phase 2 (where some villages were randomly selected to receive no follow-up visits), Blattman et al 2013 estimate that the follow-up component was responsible for about $2.01 per month of the net earnings increase. “Those assigned to any follow-up report 27% higher cash earnings, a statistically significant increase. In absolute terms the impact is small—about 5,000 UGX per month, or USD 2.01. Since cash earnings are so low in this group, however, the relative impact on the business is substantial.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 42.
      • We therefore estimate that WINGS increased beneficiaries’ monthly net earnings by $4.49/month ($6.50-$2.01) after the effects of follow-up are subtracted out. Please note that, even after subtracting out follow-up effects, these participants still benefitted from business skills training, the requirement to create a business plan and (in some cases) business networking training in addition to the $150 grant. We are unable to disentangle the effects of these components of WINGS but would guess that the grant was responsible for most of the earnings increase.

    • 192
      • Our mean monthly return: $4.49/$150 = 3.0%
      • Our mean annual return: 12*$4.49/$150 = 35.9%
      • These calculations assume that the earnings increases observed after 18 months are permanent. We would guess that this assumption is accurate.
      • Assuming (unrealistically but for the sake of argument) that no services other than the grant had any effect and varying other assumptions about time horizon and discount rate, Blattman et al 2013 estimates that the average lifetime ROI on the $150 grant was between 18% and 1,577%. Blattman et al 2013, pg. 30, Table 4.

    • 193
      • According to Blattman et al 2013, pg. 30, Table 4B, the total per-person cost of WINGS (including overhead, follow-up, group dynamics training, business training, targeting & disbursement) was 1,720,063 UGX. The cost of the grant alone was 300,000 UGX and the cost of follow-up was 696,832 UGX (1,658,537 UGX – 961705 UGX). The cost of overhead, group dynamics training, business training, targeting & disbursement was 723,231 UGX = 1,729,063 (cost of entire program) – 696,832 (cost of follow-up) – 300,000 (cost of grant).
      • Therefore, these additional services cost more than double the amount of the grant itself.

    • 194
      • “Our household spending measure increases UGX 11,741 (USD 4.72) from the program, which is a 33% increase over the control group (Figure 8).” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 16.
      • WINGS lead to a mean 43% increase in an index of household wealth index and a median 174% increase in that index. Blattman et al 2013, pg. 15, Figure 8.
      • ”Household wealth index: This is an index, scaled 0 to 1, of the household’s durable assets (e.g. furniture) and housing quality, and so reflects wealth and potential for long term consumption and spending.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 15
      • “We also see an increase in wealth. The absolute value of the index does not have an easy or natural interpretation. It is an approximate ranking of households. The average and median treatment effects are large and positive, and statistically robust, implying that WINGS clients substantially increase their durable assets relative to the control group. We can interpret these results as saying that the increased income from the intervention is channeled largely into short-term as well as durable consumption, raising standards of living.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 16.
      • “Savings triples on average (sic), going from UGX 40,740 (USD 16.36) to UGX 169,862 (USD 68.22).” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 17.
      • Savings increase by 319% relative to the control group. Blattman et al 2013, pg. 17, Figure 10.
      • Savings increase by $68.22-$16.36 = $51.86.

    • 195
      • ”Many of these villages are quite small, and the WINGS client households often represented 15 to 25% of the households.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 34.
      • “The research team visited all the treatment and control villages after the completion of Phase 1 and surveyed about 2,500 randomly chosen households who did not participate in the WINGS program. The survey collected detailed information on income, entrepreneurial activity, labor supply, savings, as well as consumption and expenditure of non-participant households. Comparing the responses of non-participants in Phase 1 versus Phase 2 villages sheds light on the community-wide effects of the WINGS program.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 34.

    • 196

      “In the realm of the survey, detailed data on community prices was collected, and a price index created. In Phase 1 communities this price index is two percent lower than in Phase 2 communities. This suggests that WINGS increases the supply of scarce traded goods and stimulates competition between microenterprises, driving down consumer prices.” Blattman et al 2013, p. 34.

    • 197

      “Preliminary results further suggest that WINGS crowds out profits of existing micro-enterprises. In theory, existing micro-enterprises are affected through two mechanisms. On the one hand, higher competition may crowd-out sales. On the other hand, because WINGS participants spend part of their income gains on consumer goods, sales of existing micro-enterprises may increase. In practice, we find that the former effect slightly dominates the latter. Profits of existing micro-enterprises fall by on average 2,500USH per month (roughly 12 percent). Labor supply of non-participants to micro-enterprise activities, however, is not affected.
      Furthermore, WINGS tends to affect the agricultural labor market. WINGS participants spend less time working on other households’ plots. Lower agricultural labor supply in turn tends to slightly drive up agricultural wages. While WINGS participants spend less time working on other households’ plots, nonparticipant households do spend half a day per month more. This is accompanied by an increase in labor income of 1,200 USH per month. The labor supply effect varies across non-participant households. While households not having a micro-enterprise show an increase of half a day per month, households operating a micro-enterprise spent only a quarter of a day/month more working on other peoples’ plots.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 35.

    • 198

      “Examples of community hostility include having serious conflicts with other community members, having community members say things to insult or hurt you or your children, or experiencing unprovoked aggression from other community members. We find that WINGS beneficiaries, on average, report 38.1 percent more hostility than people in the control group. This difference is statistically significant, but it is important to note that this is a very small absolute difference. The community hostility index ranges from a possible score of 0, meaning no hostility experienced, to 12, an indication of high hostility. As shown in Table 3, the mean score among the control group is 0.70, a very low hostility score. Therefore, an increase of 38.1 percent among the treatment group results in a mean score that is still less than 1 on this index.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 28.

    • 199

      “In general, however, we see little health and social effects, positive or negative, of the intervention on beneficiaries, despite the evident poverty impact.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 23.

    • 200

      Carolina Toth, Field Director of GiveDirectly, email to GiveWell, October 24, 2013

    • 201
      • “We presented clients with a pile of stones and a sheet with pictures of twelve kinds of expenditures (which we classify later on into these four categories). Clients were asked to allocate the stones according to how they spent the grant, and the proportions are calculated from the relative balance of stone.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 38.
      • >“Both treatment and control groups report about 36,000 UGX (USD 14.49) in spending. . . . The results differ in the level—if the clients had spent a quarter to a third of the grant on business, we would expect 90,000 to 120,000 UGX in spending (USD 36.15 – 48.20).” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 39.

    • 202

      "The data for our analysis come from surveys of stores and households conducted in the experimental villages by the Mexican National Institute of Health both before and after the program was introduced. Baseline data were collected in the final quarter of 2003 and the first quarter of 2004, before villagers knew they would be receiving the program. Follow-up data were collected two years later in the final quarter of 2005, about one year after PAL transfers began in these villages. Our measure of post-program prices comes from a survey of local food stores. Enumerators collected prices for fixed quantities of 66 individual food items, from a maximum of three stores per village, though typically data were collected from one or two stores per village." Cunha, De Giorgi and Jayachandran 2011, Pg 14-15.

    • 203

      Cunha, De Giorgi and Jayachandran 2011, Table 2, Pg 35.

    • 204

      "Our final data set contains 6 basic PAL goods (corn flour, rice, beans, pasta, oil, fortified milk), 3 supplementary PAL goods (canned fish, packaged breakfast cereal, and lentils), and 51 non-PAL goods" Cunha, De Giorgi and Jayachandran 2011, Pg 15. However, the authors report only the change in prices for the PAL goods.

    • 205

      Angelucci and De Giorgi 2009 “To test for effects on the goods market, we first compare prices in treatment and control localities. To do so, we consider village prices by good over time. We provide details on the creation of the price variables in the Appendix, as well as estimates of the price differences between treatment and control villages (Tables A3 and A4). While we find a small positive effect on 5 out of 36 food prices in November 1998, prices of staples such as rice, beans, corn, and chicken do not change. Therefore, we do not expect any substantial increase in the cost of the food basket. Moreover, we find no food price change in the later waves, nor evidence of changes for non-food prices. The evidence presented here is consistent with earlier work by Hoddinott et al. (2000).” Pg 21.

      However, the increases occur in only a small portion of a typical family's basket of goods and only in the first of three follow-up surveys, leading the authors to conclude “that, perhaps with the exception of a minor price increase for some goods in the end of 1998, [Oportunidades] does not significantly change prices in treatment areas.”

      Angelucci and De Giorgi 2009 Online appendix, pg 7. Full quote: “We find a small positive effect on some food prices in November 1998. Prices of onions (p2), lemons (p8), eggs (p26), and coffee (p34) are significantly higher in treatment than in control areas. At the same time, though, the price of fish (p23) is significantly lower. Despite the fact that onions, eggs, and coffee are commonly consumed foods (Hoddinott et al., (2000)), we do not expect these price changes to increase the cost of the food basket substantially, because prices of staples such as rice, beans, corn, and chicken do not change. Second, there is no price change in the later waves. Third, if we consider the pooled waves, the prices of 6 items
      increase, while the prices of 3 goods decrease in the observed time, out of a total of 36 items by 3 waves. This amounts to roughly 8% of good prices changing. We believe that, perhaps with the exception of a minor price increase for some goods in the end of 1998, Progresa does not significantly change prices in treatment areas.”

      Fiszbein and Schady 2009 adds that "The lack of impact on wages and prices of consumer goods is not surprising. In most countries in which CCTs have been evaluated, labor and goods markets are sufficiently developed so that both labor and goods are largely tradable. CCTs may induce larger local demand for goods and lower local supply of labor, and, in the short run, prices may change to reflect these imbalances; in the long run, however, prices should return to their initial equilibrium" (Pg 122).

    • 206

      Angelucci and De Giorgi 2009, Table 1.

    • 207

      “In the realm of the survey, detailed data on community prices was collected, and a price index created. In Phase 1 communities this price index is two percent lower than in Phase 2 communities. This suggests that WINGS increases the supply of scarce traded goods and stimulates competition between microenterprises, driving down consumer prices.” Blattman et al 2013, p. 34.

    • 208
      • ”There are no significant village-level effects on any variable group, suggesting that cash transfers to a group of particularly disadvantaged households within these villages did not impact the general village-level economy.” Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 22.
      • Standard errors on these estimates appear relatively large. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 38. However, the study does not include a complete description of how these indices were constructed so we are unsure of whether these estimates include the possibility of meaningful village-level economic effects.

    • 209

      “In practice, CCTs appear to have had, at most, modest disincentives for adult work. Two studies (Parker and Skoufias 2000; Skoufias and di Maro 2006) examine the effects of Oportunidades on adult labor supply; neither finds evidence of disincentive effects. The data used by Edmonds and Schady 2011 suggest that the BDH program in Ecuador had no effects on adult labor supply; in a similar vein, Filmer and Schady (2009c) report that adult labor supply was largely unaffected by the CESSP program in Cambodia. Only in Nicaragua is there some evidence of significant negative effects on adult work: [Maluccio and Flores 2005] show that the RPS resulted in a significant reduction in hours worked by adult men in the preceding week (by about 6 hours), with no effect among adult women.” Fiszbein and Schady 2009, Pgs 117-119.

    • 210
      • “The program increases total hours worked per week by 4.1 in 2010 and 5.5 in 2012—a 17% increase in labor supply relative to controls both years. This increase is almost entirely in skilled trades. Treatment also results in a very small but statistically significant increase in high-skill wage labor, which includes teaching, health work, government jobs, or other semi-skilled wage work. As a consequence, by 2010, 44% of the treatment group report at least one hour worked in a skilled trade, rising to 48% by 2012. Thus participation and hours in a skilled trade are 2 to 2.5 times greater than in the control group. The treatment group does not decrease their hours in other activities, however. Agricultural hours rise at the same rate in the treatment and control groups. Moreover, even in 2012, the treatment group still works twice as many hours in agriculture hours as skilled work. Trades remain a supplement to income, and young adults are primarily engaged in agriculture. Only 7% of the treatment group report 30 or more hours a week in a trade, 4 pp more than the control group. Most are simply adding this new high-skill trade to their portfolio of work activities.” Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013, pg. 20.
      • Participating in WINGS caused a 61% increase in employment hours, which consisted of a 41% increase in hours spent on subsistence work and a 79% increase in hours spent on market activities. Blattman et al 2013, pg. 16, Figure 9.

    • 211

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, pg. 33, Table 5.

    • 212

      The evidence we have seen cannot distinguish between:

      • income effects: families using income from conditional cash transfers to offset income from child labor, and therefore reducing the amount of hours worked by children; and
      • conditionality effects: since many conditional cash transfer programs require school attendance in order to qualify for transfers, families may reduce the number of hours worked by children in order to qualify for the transfers.

      These effects differ in that they have disparate predictions for the effects of unconditional cash transfers on child labor.

      Summarizing the evidence, Fiszbein and Schady (2009) states, “several CCTs have been successful in reducing child work. Frequently, these impacts have been concentrated among older children. Table 4.5 shows that Oportunidades reduced child work among older children, aged 12–17, especially among boys (for whom baseline levels of child work also were substantially higher). Skoufias and Parker (2001) also show that domestic work decreased substantially, especially for girls.
      In Ecuador, Edmonds and Schady (2008) shows that the Bono de Desarrollo Humano program had very large effects on child work among those children most vulnerable to transitioning from schooling to work. Those effects are concentrated in work for pay away from the child’s home. BDH transfers, on the other hand, had small effects on child time allocation at peak school attendance ages and among children already out of school at baseline. In Cambodia, the CESSP program, which gives transfers to children in transition from primary to lower-secondary school, reduced work for pay by 11 percentage points (Filmer and Schady 2009c).
      Other CCT programs also appear to have reduced child work. In Nicaragua, the Red de Proteción Social program reduced child work by 3–5 percentage points among children aged 7–13 (Maluccio, John A., and Rafael Flores. 2005). Furthermore, the fraction of children who only studied (as opposed to worked and studied, only worked, or neither worked nor studied) increased significantly (from 59 percent to 84 percent) as a result of the RPS (Maluccio 2005). Yap, Sedlacek, and Orazem (2008) estimate the effects of the Brazilian Programa de Erradicação do Trabalho Infantil (PETI) program, another precursor of the Bolsa Família program. PETI gave out conditional transfers to secondary school-age children enrolled in school. Stipends were given directly to students, not to the families and were conditional on school attendance and participation in special training workshops. PETI beneficiaries reduced substantially their probability of working. Attanasio et al. (2006), however, finds no effect of the Familias en Acción program on child work in Colombia (although the program does appear to have reduced the amount of time dedicated to domestic chores). Glewwe and Olinto (2004) find no effect of the PRAF program on child work in Honduras.

      Two recent papers consider the impact of CCTs on child work when the transfer is conditional on school attendance for only one child in the household and that child has siblings. Programs of this nature could have positive or negative spillovers for other siblings. Positive outcomes include if the income effect reduces child work for all children, if transfers increase the bargaining capacity of women within the household, or if the social marketing by the program leads parents to reduce child work even for children whose school attendance is not monitored. Negative impact could include parents compensating for the reduction in work of one child by increasing the work of other siblings. Barrera-Osorio et al. (2008) analyze Subsidios Condicionados a la Asistencia Escolar, a pilot CCT program in Bogotá, Colombia. This program randomized assignment to individual children rather than households, and made transfers directly to students rather than to their parents. Barrera-Osorio et al. show that, within the same household, a student selected into the program is 2 percentage points more likely to attend school and works about 1 hour less than a sibling who has not been selected; however, the beneficiary’s sibling – particularly if this sibling is a girl – is less likely to attend school than are children in households that received no cash transfer at all. In contast, Filmer and Schady (2009c) find that the CESSP program in Cambodia had no effect on the school enrollment of a beneficiary’s ineligible siblings.” pgs 115-116.

    • 213

      Fiszbein and Schady 2009, pg 114, “[T]able 4.1 shows that, for most countries, the impact of the transfer is generally somewhat smaller than the magnitude of the transfer (when both are normalized as a fraction of the consumption or income of households in the control group). The difference between these two values may be a result of behavioral changes by CCT beneficiaries, which partly offset the value of the transfer itself. We now turn to a discussion of the evidence on these possible offsetting effects, focusing on impacts on child labor, adult labor, remittances, fertility, and spillovers and other general equilibrium effects.”

      Other potential explanations might include:

      • reductions in adult labor in favor of increased leisure time
      • increased savings or investment in productive assets
      • errors in measuring consumption, leading to attenuation in the estimated increase associated with receiving cash transfers
      • misappropriation of transfers.

    • 214

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, Table 10, Pg 38. Haushofer and Shapiro 2013's estimate of the program's effects on an index of crime seems to have large standard errors, however. The methodology used to construct the index is not described, so we cannot tell whether the estimate excludes the possibility of large increases in crime.

    • 215

      "Additional variables in table 9 show the frequency of any episode of physical, sexual or emotional violence in the last six months, and the percentage of respondents who believe that domestic violence is justified in some instances. The point estimates for these variables suggest a reduction in domestic violence, although none are individually different from zero at conventional significance levels." Haushofer and Shapiro 2013, Pg 21.

    • 216

      “Examples of community hostility include having serious conflicts with other community members, having community members say things to insult or hurt you or your children, or experiencing unprovoked aggression from other community members. We find that WINGS beneficiaries, on average, report 38.1 percent more hostility than people in the control group. This difference is statistically significant, but it is important to note that this is a very small absolute difference. The community hostility index ranges from a possible score of 0, meaning no hostility experienced, to 12, an indication of high hostility. As shown in Table 3, the mean score among the control group is 0.70, a very low hostility score. Therefore, an increase of 38.1 percent among the treatment group results in a mean score that is still less than 1 on this index.” Blattman et al 2013, pg. 28.

    • 217

      Aker et al. 2011

    • 218

      "Excluding the cost of the mobile phones, the per-recipient cost of the zap intervention falls to $8.80 per recipient. Thus, while the initial costs of the zap program were significantly higher, variable costs were 30 percent higher in the manual cash distribution villages." Aker et al. 2011, Pg 12.

    • 219

      Aker et al. 2011, Pg 10.

    • 220

      Aker et al. 2011, Tables 4 and 5.

    • 221 Fiszbein and Schady 2009.
    • 222

      Lagarde, Haines, and Palmer. 2009

    • 223

      Haushofer and Shapiro 2013

    • 224

      Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez 2013 and Blattman et al 2013.

    • 225

      The file is available here.

      The file is broken into three worksheets. "Main set of RCTs" includes the recent studies that have most influenced our views about cash transfers. This sheet primarily consists of studies that clearly contained evidence of: 1) propensity to invest cash transfers; 2) propensity to spend cash transfers on alcohol, tobacco, or other "temptation goods; 3) recipients' returns on investment; 4) hostility or resentment from cash transfers; 5) effects on inflation or village economies, or other economic effects on non-recipients; 6) differing effects between UCTs and CCTs.

      “Useful non-RCTs and comments” includes relevant non-randomized studies, blog posts or commentary.

      “Other results from Google Scholar” contains information from other recent studies of cash transfers that did not strongly affect our overall views. Most of these studies fall into one of a few categories:

      • non-randomized
      • re-analyses of existing data that focus on various potential secondary benefits or costs of cash transfers. There is widely accessible data relevant to some of the biggest public cash transfer programs, leading researchers to test for effects on a very large number of outcomes that were not pre-registered. For example, we have recently seen studies of Progresa/Oportunidades's effects on elderly mortality and child development. We believe that this type of study is more likely to be affected by publication bias/data mining, so we have not carefully reviewed them.
      • studies of CCTs whose results we would not expect to hold for UCTs (primarily studies that report outcomes that are directly related to the conditions placed on recipients).


    Source URL: https://www.givewell.org/international/technical/programs/cash-transfers/2013-version